Home
/
RELIGION & LIBERTY
/
When Scottish Sages Christened Liberal
When Scottish Sages Christened Liberal
Jul 12, 2025 4:24 AM

  Big data is often a big bust, but not always. Big data has resolved a longstanding debate about when “liberal” first acquired a political meaning.

  And, what do you know, Friedrich Hayek was right.

  I use big data in a scholarly article published in the Journal of Contextual Economics, showing decisively that a political meaning was christened “liberal’—for the first time—by a bevy of Scottish thinkers. The story, in short, is this: The adjective “liberal” had a long, rich history as a non-political word in moral discourse. Several Scotsmen, including George Turnbull, David Hume, and Adam Ferguson, had made pregnant remarks using “liberal”—remarks that may have suggested using the adjective to describe a political attitude. But the “liberal” christening was really kicked off by William Robertson in 1769, and in 1776, Adam Smith went all-in, in The Wealth of Nations. The political meaning was, essentially, a policy posture, premised on a stable, functional system of governmental authority. The policy posture is one of leaving people be, of “allowing every man to pursue his own interest his own way,” within the bounds of commutative justice. The “liberal” christening took.

  Hayek Was Right

  In 1960, Hayek questioned the consensus view that “liberal” first obtained a political meaning after 1800 on the Continent, from which Britain then imported the term. Hayek suggested otherwise:

  I am more inclined to believe that it derives from the use of the term by Adam Smith in such passages as W.o.N., II, 41: “the liberal system of free exportation and free importation” and p. 216: “allowing every man to pursue his own interest his own way, upon the liberal plan of equality, liberty, and justice.”

  Hayek’s view had had little hope of overturning the consensus. Before the digitization of millions of texts, mounting a case for Hayek’s view would mean spending years gathering a few score quotations. Tedious quotations, cherry-picked by one of those Hayek votaries with an axe to grind, from the vast uncharted forests of innumerable texts, could not get far. Such curiosa could easily be ignored and dismissed.

  But, around 2012, the data came readily to hand, thanks to the Google Books Ngram Viewer. My utilization of data is simple and straightforward. There are no hidden assumptions of the sort that often attend big-data claims. There are no complicated models behind my results. In fact, there are no models at all. The data clearly show origination and sustainment. They also show who got there first. The adjective “liberal” first took a political meaning in Smith’s time, and that meaning was sustained ever after, and exported from Britain to the Continent.

  So, basically, Hayek was right. But I do not wish to overstate matters. First, Hayek’s passage above suggests that Smith christened his policy views “liberal” quite single-handedly. Although Smith looms large in the christening, he did not do it single-handedly, and he was not the very first. More importantly, the conclusions from the data do not deny that the nouns liberalism and liberal came to mean more than, or things in addition to, Smith’s “liberal plan” or “liberal system.” “Liberalism” was quickly somewhat polysemous, and over time it grew more so, and especially after 1890 or so, when it began to take on a meaning directly at odds with Smithian liberalism (the “New Liberalism”).

  Hayek says in an encyclopedia entry of “liberalism” that Smith’s outlook continued as one strand of liberalism. A second strand during the nineteenth century was associated with “the Continental tradition.” Hayek says that “liberal” had on the Continent a stronger connotation of rationalism and constructivism than in Britain. Also, what often occupied the highest place on the Continent was “the demand for the self-determination of each group concerning its form of government.” Britain was an island. Many of its writers, from about Hume’s time, worked with the assumption of a stable polity—an assumption that island geography helped to make apt. Continental politics, however, were less stable, and Continental polities more undulating. To have “the science of a legislator,” as Smith called the policy outlook offered by The Wealth of Nations, you first need a legislature.

  To abandon the word “liberal,” with its venerable pre-political history and its long history as signifier of a worthy political outlook, would be to abandon our history.

  Those points from Hayek about different early liberalisms strike me as valuable, even if I doubt some smaller points in Hayek’s “Liberalism” encyclopedia entry.I suspect that liberals throughout most of the nineteenth century, such as Benjamin Constant, F. P. G. Guizot, and Alexis de Tocqueville, all of whom Hayek mentions in the encyclopedia entry, generally shared Smith’s precepts and judgments on “the science of a legislator,” and that is why they were called liberals.

  As Hayek indicates, in Great Britain it was not until the last decades of the nineteenth century that one vein of “liberals” began to subvert the Smithian spine. That subversion proved effective; today, in the United States and Canada, “liberal” is applied to the parties more inclined toward the governmentalization of social affairs and more opposed to Smith’s idea of “allowing every man to pursue his own interest his own way.” Hayek wrote in 1973:

  The name “liberal” is coming to be used, even in Europe, as has for some time been true of the USA, as a name for essentially socialist aspirations, because, in the words of J. A. Schumpeter, “as a supreme but unintended compliment, the enemies of the system of private enterprise have thought it wise to appropriate the label.”

  “Liberal” Was a Decision

  It seems clear to me that in Scotland in the mid-eighteenth century there was a nest of thinkers who saw, developed, and advanced a political outlook in need of a name. That the outlook christened “liberal” was destined to have that particular name is not so clear. But “liberal” was indeed what emerged. I do not suppose that these thinkers fancied that their outlook was something that they had birthed. I use “christening” not for its birthing connotation but for its naming connotation.

  It is tantalizing to imagine that members of the Scottish nest discussed what name to select. When we name a child or a boat, we formulate alternative options and weigh the options. What alternatives might have been considered? I do not know of direct evidence, however, of any such explicit, coordinated discussion of that kind. Still, Robertson, Smith, and others did consciously select the adjective liberal; they started to use that adjective in a novel way, thus christening their outlook “liberal.” It was a semantic decision. Each writer may have made the decision in the solitude of his study, but it was a decision.

  Was the word liberal a bad choice? On that question, I maintain that no matter what word they had chosen, if it had taken, it would, subsequently, have been abused and pilfered. Man is destined to what resulted in Babel, particularly in things political.

  I believe that “liberal” was a good choice, for reasons elaborated both in my article and in Erik Matson’s Southern Economic Journal article “What Is Liberal about Adam Smith’s ‘Liberal Plan’?” At any rate, “liberal” is the choice that was made. To abandon the word “liberal,” with its venerable pre-political history (“liberal arts,” “liberal sciences,” “liberality”) and its long history as signifier of a worthy political outlook, would be to abandon our history.

  Editors Note: This is a condensed version of an article published in the Journal of Contextual Economics.

Comments
Welcome to mreligion comments! Please keep conversations courteous and on-topic. To fosterproductive and respectful conversations, you may see comments from our Community Managers.
Sign up to post
Sort by
Show More Comments
RELIGION & LIBERTY
Turkey: Islam's bridge to religious and economic liberty?
You say there's a growing sector in Turkish society that is engaged with the market economy and that's a healthy trend. Do you see that trend continuing in Turkey? There is in this economy a capitalist development, and this is important. In the past, generally speaking, the religious people were more of the peasant class and they were mostly in agriculture--not in modern industrial production. Generally speaking, the bourgeois, the people who were the capitalists, who were owners of...
The scandal of evangelical politics
In The Scandal of Evangelical Politics, Ronald J. Sider attempts to construct a methodology for evangelical Christians to participate faithfully in the political process. His construct is a backlash—to a degree—of the political monopolization of the religious right and its influence in politics. The book is a response to past evangelical involvement, which Sider sees as largely being a failure and highly contradictory. And while his methodology does not necessarily contradict any political goals of Christian conservatives, and is...
Editor's note
Currently there are serious concerns about economic prosperity in a nation that has for so long benefited from tremendous economic growth and stability. Likewise, some are deeply troubled about government proposed solutions and cures for our economic ailments. South Carolina's governor Mark Sanford brings substantial thought and credibility to free-market ideas while articulating the danger of greater centralized power. Those paying attention to current events will be well aware that Governor San ford has risen to be perhaps the...
Power and corruption in Catholic Boston
Lord Acton’s quotation concerning the corrupting effect of power is widely known. Less so is the fact that the target of his criticism on that particular occasion was the power possessed not by government but by church officials. Acton’s understanding of ecclesiastical authority (as distinct from power) is debatable, but his insight into human nature is not. A case study—not that we need another to file away in the vast archives of the history of human frailty—is the collapse...
"Brand loyalty" in the American religious marketplace
Earlier this year, the Pew Forum for Religion and Public Life released the first installment of a truly impressive study based upon a massive survey of more than 35,000 Americans. Its portrait of the American religious landscape attracted a great deal of media attention, typically focusing on three or four principal themes. If you were to read only the press accounts, here's what you would know: While Americans are still overwhelmingly -- at least nominally -- Christian (78.4 percent...
Taking a stand: An interview with Governor Mark Sanford
You’ve taken a very principled approach in working for smaller government, lower taxes, individual liberty, and, for fostering a culture of personal responsibility. Those principles are taking a battering in Washington today. Can anything turn the tide? George Washington and his fairly battered band of patriots were facing far greater odds. The situation looked much more bleak. And yet they were resolved to creating the perfect union that they believed in. And they ultimately prevailed against incredibly long odds....
Spiritual enterprise: Doing virtuous business
With the onset of the financial crisis and economic downturn, there has been a lot of discussion about the future of the free economy in this country. Scandal and corruption among executives and financial institutions has of course played a significant part in fueling the discussion. While paying tribute to the free economy and the wealth it has created, Theodore Roosevelt Malloch also looks to reinforce and renew the foundations of virtuous business in Spiritual Enterprise. Malloch agrees that...
Cardinal Bertone's "The Ethics of the Common Good in the Social Doctrine of the Church"
Cardinal Tarcisio Bertone, the Vatican's Secretary of State and effectively the second most important official in the Catholic Church, takes a close look at economic globalization and the social nature of markets in a book published in September, in Italian and Russian, by the Libreria Editrice Vaticana. Bertone’s book, “The Ethics of the Common Good in the Social Doctrine of the Church” (L'etica del Bene Comune nella Dottrina Sociale della Chiesa) is also notable for its ecumenical character; it...
The envy trap
It is one of the great puzzles, true throughout all human history, that during an economic downturn, people turn on the rich. They call for them to be taxed, harassed, beaten, and jailed. Because they have money when others are losing money, envy is unleashed and encouraged by the political establishment. It amounts to a kind of lashing out at the most conspicuous target, even though doing so won’t actually plish anything. On the face of it, this should...
Busting a pop culture illusion
For the past several decades, American popular culture has frequently promulgated an idea central to modern liberalism: the idea of a life without limits, that we can have everything we want with out having to make hard choices. That assumption is especially evident in Walt Disney movies, and not only in recent ones. Fortunately, the makers of some pop culture products see the absurdity and danger of that notion. The life-without-limits mindset, derived most directly from the ideas of...
Related Classification
Copyright 2023-2025 - www.mreligion.com All Rights Reserved