Home
/
RELIGION & LIBERTY ONLINE
/
There Are No Alternatives to Free Market Capitalism
There Are No Alternatives to Free Market Capitalism
Oct 6, 2024 11:01 AM

Exploring Catholic social teaching in relation to economics is fine, but if we’re too open-minded about seeking a new mon good” capitalism, our brains might fall out.

Read More…

Alexander William Salter’s new book, The Political Economy of Distributism: Property, Liberty, and the Common Good, is an odd fish. It begs questions, contains numerous chapters that consist mostly of lengthy quotations, and at times seems to contradict itself, yet in the end it affirms an essential truth that we may forget from time to time, that private property is essential for political freedom. That it does so in a meandering fashion is not a mendation against reading it. In fact, I mend it—just be sure to read it with a critical eye.

Salter begins with a discussion of how many politicians mentators have reintroduced discussion of mon good into the American political discourse, particularly in how it relates to capitalism. However, in discussing the speeches of Marco Rubio and the works of Patrick Deneen and Adrian Vermeule and then connecting them to older strains of thought that form the meat of the book, Salter engages in serial assumptions that amount to question begging. First, mon good capitalism is worth distinguishing from capitalism itself. Secondly, that Catholic social teaching is the best place to look mon good capitalism. Thirdly, that the school of political economy briefly popular in Britain in the 1920s and ’30s, distributism, patible mon good capitalism.

To tackle these in reverse order: Distributism is explained by Salter with extensive reference to the works of the Anglo-French politician and writer Hilaire Belloc, and the great novelist, poet, and thinker G.K. Chesterton, who together provided the intellectual core of the distributist philosophy. Their professed position was that they were neither capitalist nor collectivist, representing instead a Third Way.

This third position led to some unfortunate associations. When I was a student debater in the 1980s, I visited the Glasgow University Union, whose parliamentary debate system recognized six political groupings, of which one was still distributist. When I asked my host what this party represented, never having heard the term before, he replied, “Non-racist fascists.” Belloc is still regarded with significant distaste in his native France. It takes until the penultimate footnote of the book for Salter to acknowledge this problem. My own impressions of Belloc are rather more favorable: he was an excellent president of the Oxford Union in the 1890s (when he was regularly characterized as a socialist).

As an aside, Salter really needs to learn the art of paraphrasing. He relies on extensive quotations from these men’s works, taking up almost 100 pages of the 220-page book. This es a serious problem with Chesterton, as florid a writer as es, whose flourishes therefore suffer from being quoted shorn of their surroundings.

Those hundred pages thereby e quite a slog, especially as Salter understandably pauses to point out where their economics is lacking, simply wrong, or in some cases just plain nuts. While Salter should mended for his forthrightness in these cases, it distracts from his argument that distributism has important insights that we need to pay attention to. These amount, I think it is fair to say, to the following: that private property is essential to political liberty and that es with a “political externality” in terms of costs to political liberty that we ought to think about ways to address. This could probably have been summarized in far fewer pages.

The second assumption is best illustrated by a long discussion that takes up another third of the book—that of the works of the German thinker Wilhelm Roepke, a Lutheran who represents the ordoliberal philosophy that helped Germany recover from the depredations of Nazism. Salter argues, with some evidence, that Roepke was influenced by distributism and was a proponent of Catholic social theory. However, the word Catholic barely appears in the chapters about Roepke, and his economics, of which Salter plainly and rightly approves, are far different from the error-strewn economics of the distributists. So while much is made of Belloc and Chesterton’s Catholicism, their economic thought is derided, but in contrast the influence of Catholicism on Roepke’s correct ordoliberalism is left understated. There’s a strong case to be made, as Samuel Gregg has shown, that Roepke was both influenced by and criticized Catholic social teaching, but Salter oddly fails to make it.

Finally, in his obvious approval of Roepke’s economics, Salter shows how weak the case is mon good capitalism is in any appreciable sense different from free market economics as generally understood. For instance, Salter makes much of the idea that the state has a role to play as guardian petition through antitrust law, but Roepke makes the case, as do virtually all free market economists, that monopoly is almost always the creation of the state. petition is part of mon good, and I think Salter shows that is, then surely the first duty of mon good government is to remove the barriers petition that regulation and protectionism erect. That is exactly what traditional free market economics would suggest as well.

So how mon good capitalism differentiate itself from traditional free market capitalism? Salter’s first and most important insight from his review of distributism and Roepke is that private property is essential for political liberty. mon good capitalism should emphasize property rights at its core. Yet even here, there is little difference from free enterprise capitalism. The Nobel Prize–winning economist Ronald Coase emphasized that most of the problems of economic externalities were the result of badly allocated property rights. And free market environmentalists routinely point out, for instance, that the majority of America’s land west of the Mississippi is publicly owned to the detriment of American citizens who could own and use the land.

Indeed, one of the great insights of modern free enterprise thinking is Hernando de Soto’s idea of the mystery of capital. He points out that formal land titling enables people in the developing world to utilize that title as a source of capital. Traditional societies where all land is owned by the chief and corrupt polities that confuse land titling are equally guilty of removing this source of capital from the people. We should therefore always be looking for policies that enable access to capital—even for the landless. People as old as I am might remember that one of Margaret Thatcher’s most successful policies was to allow tenants to buy their state-owned “council houses.” But if Mrs. Thatcher was a distributist, I’m a Dutchman.

As for the political externalities of capitalism, perhaps Salter is right that political liberty is worth paying a premium for. However, maybe we should try other things first. Hayek himself, for instance, argued that we need to strengthen the property rights of owners of corporations as a form of discipline on corporate management back in 1960. Part of his suggestion was a ban on corporations voting on other corporations’ shareholder resolutions. This would do a great deal to lessen the power of activist corporations like Blackrock that use their economic power to influence corporations to intrude into the political space and crowd out individual political liberty.

The non-economic contributions of the distributists and Roepke are probably more important here. Political liberty, they agree, requires a strong moral consensus among the people and a government that backs that up. As Roepke said, free enterprise requires

a general acceptance of such norms of conduct as willingness to abide by the rules of the game and to respect the rights of others, to maintain professional integrity and professional pride, and to avoid deceit, corruption, and the manipulation of the power of the state for personal selfish ends.

This is, of course, right, and it is not something economics alone can plish. It reflects something Edmund Burke said: “Men are qualified for civil liberty in exact proportion to their disposition to put moral chains upon their own appetites.” Burke was in turn a great friend and admirer of the father of modern capitalism, Adam Smith.

In his dissection of the bad economic arguments of Belloc and Chesterton, and his drawing to our attention the good economics of Wilhelm Roepke, Salter does us a great service. When we hear modern voices echo the policies, if not the arguments, of the distributists, we should remember that however good their policies sound, they won’t work. Instead, if we want mon good capitalism, we should look more to ordoliberalism than to distributism.

Comments
Welcome to mreligion comments! Please keep conversations courteous and on-topic. To fosterproductive and respectful conversations, you may see comments from our Community Managers.
Sign up to post
Sort by
Show More Comments
RELIGION & LIBERTY ONLINE
U.S. Commission on International Religious Freedom releases 2018 report
Yesterday, the U.S. Commission on International Religious Freedom (USCIRF) released itsInternational Religious Freedom Reportfor 2018.A wide range of U.S. government agencies and offices use the reports for such efforts as shaping policy and conducting diplomacy. The Secretary of State also uses the reports to help determine which countries have engaged in or tolerated “particularly severe violations” of religious freedom in order to designate “countries of particular concern.” “Sadly, religious freedom conditions deteriorated in many countries in 2017, often due to...
Growth miracles and growth disasters
Note: This is post #76 in a weekly video series on basic economics. Because of differences in national growth rates there can be large disparities in economic wealth among different countries. A poor country can not only grow, but it can do so quickly. It can catch up with developed countries at an astonishing rate. That’s the good news, says Alex Tabarrok in this video by Marginal Revolution University. The bad news is, while growth can skyrocket in some countries,...
‘Avengers: Infinity War’ and the danger of idolatrous ideology
Warning: This article contains a major spoiler about the plot of‘Avengers: Infinity War.’ If you haven’t seen the movie yetand don’t want it to know what happens then PLEASE STOP READING NOW. Since I was a boy I’ve loved Marvel Comics, and over the past decade I’ve loved almost everything about the Marvel Cinematic Universe (MCU). But I don’t love the latest the edition of the MCU,Avengers: Infinity War. I should love the film because it’s packed with everything I...
James Cone and the Marxist roots of black liberation theology
Rev. Dr. James Hal Cone died last week at the age of 79. Cone was a professor of systematic theology at Union Theological Seminary and the father of black liberation theology. In a 2008 Acton Commentary, Anthony Bradley provided a brief explanation of Cone’s system of black liberation theology and its roots in Marxism: Black liberation theologians James Cone and Cornel West have worked diligently to embed Marxist thought into the black church since the 1970s. For Cone, Marxism best...
Emmanuel Macron and the problem with ‘European values’
Last weekFrench President Emmanuel Macron came to the United States for a two-day summit with President Trump and an address before Congress. As Acton senior editor Rev. Ben Johnson notes at The American Spectator, Macron’s speech before Congress reveals a deep fissure within the West about its most fundamental values—a fracture es as the West faces powerful challenges from outside its borders: Macron’s speech to Congress represents one set of values: the statist orientation of the bureaucratic EU elite. Leaving...
What is the Catholic Church’s teaching on the size of government?
What is the Catholic Church’s teaching on the size of government? And what is the principle of subsidiarity? Our friends atCatholicVote.orghave put together a brief video to help answer these questions. ...
Beyond vocational hierarchies: Evangelism, social justice, and Christian mission
Throughout my conservative evangelical upbringing, I was routinely encouraged to follow the call of the “five-fold ministry,” whether from the pulpit in weekly church services or the prayer altars of summer youth camps. The implications were clear: entering so-called “vocational ministry” was a higher calling than, well, everything else. Later, in my college years at a leftist Christian university, I witnessed a lopsidedness of a different sort. Instead of being prodded into global missions, I was now encouraged to “make...
Macron’s speech offers thin gruel on Western ‘values’
For one fleeting moment in Emmanuel Macron’s speech to Congress, it seemed as though he would connect the transatlantic alliance on the firm basis of mon values. “The strength of our bonds is the source of our shared ideals,” he told lawmakers. Since 1776, the United States and France “have worked together for the universal ideals of liberty, tolerance, and equal rights.” The use of the phrase “universal values,” an ersatz substitute for Western values, preceded his assessment of the...
Loving cities well: Chris Brooks on the church’s role in economic restoration
What would happen if local churches came together to love and serve our cities? Upon hearing such a question, our minds are prone to imagine an assortment of “outreach ministries,” from food pantries to homeless shelters munity events to street evangelism.But while each of these can be a powerful channel for love and service in munities, what about the basic vision that precedes them? Before and beyond our tactical solutions to immediate needs, how can the church truly work together...
Radio Free Acton: RFA Reports on Direct Primary Care part II; Upstream on ‘Avengers: Infinity War’
On this episode of Radio Free Acton, we feature the second installment of RFA Reports. Guest Anne Marie Schieber-Dykstra, an award-winning reporter and former anchor with WOODTV Grand Rapids, talks with experts and patients on ways in which Direct Primary Care centers are providing better medical care for affordable prices. Then, on the Upstream segment, Bruce Edward Walker talks about the latest film in the Marvel Cinematic Universe: “Avengers: Infinity War” with Micah Watson, professor of political science at Calvin...
Related Classification
Copyright 2023-2024 - www.mreligion.com All Rights Reserved