Home
/
RELIGION & LIBERTY ONLINE
/
The Political Economy of Fantasy Sports
The Political Economy of Fantasy Sports
Jul 15, 2025 5:39 PM

Although it is played by about 15 million Americans and amounting to a $1.5 billion a year industry, and even though it is a growing business and worth talking about, this post is not about the real-world economics of fantasy sports.

Instead, this post is about the typical structures of fantasy leagues, particularly football (the most popular), and what these leagues can tell us about the participants’ most basic economic assumptions or impulses. I will argue that the default model in fantasy sports is one of an authoritarian and interventionist governing body, which severely restricts merce.

But just who are we talking about? As Marketplace reports, the typical fantasy sports players are “male, they’re about 36, and they own their homes.”

So what are the basic structures of fantasy leagues?

A league consists of a number of owners who each field a team. These teams are typically chosen in the form of a draft, which can be held live and in-person, live over the Internet, pleted offline puter automation. In this latter case, owners often set personalized rankings of players that puter uses to fill out the draft.

The goal is for each owner to construct a team that will score the most points according to the rules of the league. There is a great variety of scoring systems, ranging in football to TD-only leagues (where points are awarded only for touchdowns) to leagues pute scores based plex calculations of yardage, fumbles, touchdowns, and many other statistics. The advent puters and the Internet has been a key force in the popularization of fantasy sports, since many of plex calculations can now be done flawlessly and automatically puter.

Since all of these leagues are founded on statistics, this has led in some cases to a dispute over ownership of sports stats. A recent case with implications for fantasy baseball found that MLB stats are in the public domain.

So, each owner is oriented toward fielding the best-scoring team possible each week, and following the draft roster changes can be made by the addition of free agents or through trades between owners. It is with respect to trades between teams that the clearest indications of the authoritarian and interventionist nature of fantasy es out.

I have played in a number of leagues, and the traditional way that trades work is that two teams agree to swap players, and then the trade goes to the league for review. This review can be done in a number of ways, but one of the mon mirrors the real-life practice in sports trading: the league office (aka missioner”) reviews the trade.

The Sports Guy Bill Simmons, in an article addressing perennial problems in fantasy football, gets at the almost-universal impetus to have trade review:

We all know that the wrong trade can divide a fantasy league faster than the Spelling family fell apart. In my West Coast league a few years ago, the first-place team had Brett Favre and Peyton Manning. It needed a receiver and traded Manning straight up for Amani Toomer. You read the correctly. Nearly 700 angry e-mails and five near-fistfights later, the trade was somehow approved. If that wasn’t bad enough, the first-place team won the title — Toomer filled a gaping hole at receiver — and Manning’s new team finished second. From then on, we called it Toomergate. And, honestly, I never want to go through anything like that again. It was more traumatic than the last 20 minutes of “American History X.”

The point is that trade review is supposed to 1) prevent collusion among team owners and 2) prevent unfair trades from upsetting a league balance. There is pelling and dominant instinct among fantasy players to put in place structures that will plish these two things.

So why do I characterize fantasy leagues as “authoritarian”? Because, as I noted, one of the mon ways that trades are reviewed is by a single individual, missioner, typically the person who took the trouble to form the league, send out emails notifying people about league information, and generally run the day-to-day operations. As one friend of mine put it when plained about league matters this year, “You want everything to be perfect? I’ll be the first one to nominate you to set up and run the league next year.”

Once a trade is agreed upon, missioner’s job is to determine whether the trade violates either or both of the above-mentioned concerns (collusion and parity). This is often done by a sort of subjective weighting of evidence, and there are typically no clear standards with which to apply judgments for the two concerns. Often team owners can register their feelings, in the form of making an argument for or against a particular trade.

This leaves the missioner in the role of Solomon the Wise, to render judgment from on high. All this, I think, is well-characterized as “authoritarian”.

But the second characteristic of fantasy leagues I intend to show is that they tend toward intervention. That is, the assumption is that a particular trade must positively show that it meets both conditions…the trade has the burden of proof to show that it is fair. The merest hint of unbalance is often enough to get a trade “vetoed,” which has a chilling effect on merce. As Bill Simmons also notes, one of the key problem with fantasy sports is that “there are never enough trades.” The propensity for league veto is a major factor in this.

Let me give you an example from one of my leagues this year. So far, there have been four trades agreed upon. Of those four, three have been vetoed. In fact, I traded for the same player on two different occasions, only to have both trades overturned. The other vetoed trade involved missioner and another player, and I must say at least mish had the integrity to veto his own trade. The only other trade to go through is the same exact trade involving missioner, which was passed without argument after a long and heated leaguewide debate about the radical intervention and chilling effect of trade review.

The issue of missioner having to review trades in which he or she is involved gets at Bill Simmons’ proposed solution for trade review: the formation of a mittee consisting of “three unbiased outsiders who aren’t in the league but are friends with a few of the owners.” This may address the problem of corruption (which isn’t a problem in my league so far), but it doesn’t address the authoritarian interventionism.

There is, I think, a relevant Hayekian argument to be made missioner-review and/or mittee review, and that is the argument concerning diffuse information. Each owner presumably knows his or her team better than anyone else, and is therefore in a unique position to judge the defects and strengths of the team. Even with a forum for each owner to put an argument forward, missioner or mittee cannot hope to have a better perspective than the two involved owners.

Moreover, since each owner is primarily and predominantly motivated by self-interest, they have the motives most likely to see to their own benefit. These two observations have addressed the questions of knowledge and will that are most relevant to the discussion.

I think that the presumption should be in favor of trades, and that the burden of proof should lie on the side of those trying to veto a particular transaction. The default perspective should work to merce and trade, rather than authoritarianism and interventionism.

Does this mean that we need pletely do away with trade review? Not necessarily. But the structure and system of review would need to radically change from the typical current construction if it is to favor liberty and freedom of exchange over tyranny and intervention.

Comments
Welcome to mreligion comments! Please keep conversations courteous and on-topic. To fosterproductive and respectful conversations, you may see comments from our Community Managers.
Sign up to post
Sort by
Show More Comments
RELIGION & LIBERTY ONLINE
Burke vs. Paine on Choice, Obligation, and Social Order
I recently read Yuval Levin’s new book, The Great Debate: Edmund Burke, Thomas Paine, and the Birth of Right and Left, and found it remarkably rich and rewarding. Though the entire book is worthy of discussion, his chapter on choice vs. obligation is particularly helpful in illuminating one of the more elusive tensions in our social thought and action. In the chapter, Levin provides a helpful summary of how the two men differed in their beliefs about social obligation and...
Is Knowledge Of Religion Important To Culture?
We Americans are rather ignorant about religion. We claim to be a religious folk, but when es to hard-core knowledge, we don’t do well. The Pew Forum put together a baseline quiz of religious knowledge – a mere 32 multiple choice questions – and on average, Americans only got about half of them right. A few sample questions (without the multiple choice answers): Which Bible figure is most closely associated with leading the exodus from Egypt?What is Ramadan?In which religion...
The Love Of A Father And The Economy Of Family
255 Triathlons (6 Ironman distances, 7 Half Ironman), 22 Duathlons, 72 Marathons (32 Boston Marathons), 8 18.6 Milers, 97 Half Marathons, 1 20K, 37 10 Milers: That’s a lot of miles. A lot of training. A lot of numbers. It’s an economy of sorts for athletic achievement. These are some of the stats for Team Hoyt, the father-son team of Dick and Rick Hoyt who have raced together for 37 years. Rick was born with cerebral palsy in 1962, and...
Does Religion Do Us Any Good, Even If We’re Not Religious?
Is there any societal reason to protect religion? That is, do we get anything out of religion, as a society, even if we’re not religious, and is that “anything” worth protecting? Mark Movsesian thinks so. In First Things, Movsesian says religion does do good for a society – a good that is worthy of protection. Religion, munal religion, provides important benefits for everyone in the liberal state—even the non-religious. Religion encourages people to associate with and feel responsible for others,...
Why Resegregation Happens—And How School Choice Can Fix It
With its decision in Brown vs. Board of Education, the Supreme Court ended systemic racial segregation in public education. Now, sixty years later, courts have released hundreds of school districts from enforced integration—with the result being an increase in “resegregation” of public schools. Numerous media outlets have recently picked up on a story by the investigative journalism nonprofit ProPublica about schools in Tuscaloosa, Alabama. According to the report: In recent years, a new term, apartheid schools—meaning schools whose white population...
Live from Rome: Faith, State, and the Economy: Perspectives from East and West
Watch our new conference series live from Rome on April 29 at 10:00 a.m. EST. The embedded player below will display our conference stream when it es available. You can also visit the event on our Livestream page in order to see more information and to ask questions during the event. ...
Tornadoes, Disaster Relief, and the Power of the Christian Community
At the bottom of this storm and tornado roundup from The Weather Channel, there is a powerful slideshow on the devastation in Arkansas, Mississippi, and Alabama. The death count in the region stands at 31. Mississippi’s Governor Phil Bryant described yesterday as “The most active tornado day in Mississippi history.” Some people forget that it is denominational church agencies that often are the first to meet the material needs and fort to the afflicted. Southern Baptist Disaster Relief is well...
Art at Acton: ‘Perpetual Order’ and the Struggle for Permanence
Yesterday, I had the honor of contributing to a panel discussion on the art of Margaret Vega here at the Acton Institute. Her exhibition is titled, “Angels, Dinergy, and Our Relationship with Perpetual Order.” Some fuller coverage may be ing on the PowerBlog, but in the meantime I have posted the text of my presentation, “Death and the Struggle for Permanence” at Everyday Asceticism. Excerpt: Angels … represent hope amid the human struggle for permanence in a life so characterized...
Let’s All Join the Tenth Commandment Club
In our modern era, the ancient sin of covetousness primarily manifests itself in three forms: greed, theft, and arguments about inequality. The greedy selfishly desire to acquire what others have, thieves illicitly acquire what others have, and equality advocates want the government to redistribute what others have. It would be unfair, of course, to assume that all critics of inequality are driven by covetousness. But if you stripped away that sin as a motivation, the number of people who care...
Fossil Fuel Follies
The religious crusade against fossil fuels and various methods of extracting it to heat and light our homes, offices, and factories continues apace. The 2014 proxy shareholder season is a veritable spider web of networked religious-affiliated activist groups decrying coal, natural gas, oil, hydraulic fracturing and mining. Ceres, for example, reports “35 institutional investors have filed 142 resolutions in a coordinated effort to spur action by panies” on what it calls climate-related measures. Based in Boston, Mass., the nonprofit group...
Related Classification
Copyright 2023-2025 - www.mreligion.com All Rights Reserved