Home
/
RELIGION & LIBERTY ONLINE
/
Should we be nudged toward libertarian paternalism?
Should we be nudged toward libertarian paternalism?
Jan 10, 2025 3:08 PM

If the boy is father to the man, then I was raised by a profligate dunce. Even though I had learned the power pound interest in high school, I foolishly squandered my trivial savings at a time when the “eighth wonder of the world,” as Albert Einstein called it, would have had the greatest impact. Had I invested a mere $2,000 in Apple stock on my 18th birthday I would now be $252,039 richer and well on my way to being a millionaire by the time I reach retirement. Economists might say my choice was rational (it was all the money I had in the world at the time) but it certainly wasn’t optimal.

Fortunately, I had a distant relative—Uncle Sam—that stepped in to save me from my own economic petence. For example, during my first week of Marine Corps boot camp I had to fill out a form in which I had the choice to “opt out” of the Montgomery GI Bill. If I did not check the box I would have $100 a month deducted from my pay for six months and in return I would have $36,000 to use for college. Although several of my fellow recruits chose not to participate, the majority of us took the lazy way out and left the box unchecked. That act of sloth made me $35,400 richer.

My experience was an example of an action of what The Economist referred to in 2006 as the “avuncular state”: “worldly-wise, offering a nudge in the right direction, perhaps pulling strings on your behalf without your even noticing.” Advocates of this form of paternalistic governance include a number of behavioral economists who term such approaches “asymmetric paternalism”, “benign paternalism,” “cautious paternalism,” or, as Richard Thaler, the economist who won this year’s Nobel Prize in Economics, calls it, “libertarian paternalism.”

In 2009, Thaler and Cass Sunstein published a book called Nudge: Improving Decisions About Health, Wealth, and Happiness, which popularized the concept. Before that, though, they wrote an influential law review article on libertarian paternalism:

The idea of libertarian paternalism might seem to be an oxymoron, but it is both possible and legitimate for private and public institutions to affect behavior while also respecting freedom of choice. Often people’s preferences are ill-formed, and their choices will inevitably be influenced by default rules, framing effects, and starting points. In these circumstances, a form of paternalism cannot be avoided. Equipped with an understanding of behavioral findings of bounded rationality and bounded self-control, libertarian paternalists should attempt to steer people’s choices in welfare-promoting directions without eliminating freedom of choice.

“Libertarians embrace freedom of choice, and so they deplore paternalism,” note Sunstein and Thaler. “Paternalists are thought to be deeply skeptical of freedom of choice and to deplore libertarianism.” The two groups would appear to be mutually exclusive but the authors argue for a “form of paternalism, libertarian in spirit, that should be acceptable to those who are mitted to freedom of choice on grounds of either autonomy or welfare.”

A few examples they provide of how libertarian paternalism can be put into practice are:

• In an attempt to increase savings by workers, pany decides not to ask employees if they wish to participate in a 401(k) plan. Instead, the workers are automatically enrolled unless they specifically choose otherwise.

• “Sin goods”—such as junk food—are often repeatedly purchased in small quantities for short-term consumption. Because people make numerous purchases over the course of their lives rather than, for instance, a single trip to the store to purchase a lifetime supply of potato chips, they can distort their long-term consumption decisions by giving in to small preferences for immediate gratification. A way to correct for this would be to impose a per-unit tax on potato chips to induce people to consume less, and return the proceeds to consumers via a lump-sum transfer or by lowering e taxes or taxes on some modity, such as socks.

• Another approach would be to induce people with self-control problems to make “prospective choices,” making choices now that influence their future in-the-moment incentives. One way to implement this would be to impose a high presumptive tax, and then sell licenses (or vouchers) that permit people to buy the good tax-free (or at a reduced tax) in the future. For example, rather than pay $2 per pack on cigarettes, a smoker could buy a “sin license” which might cost $5,000 and entitle the holder to an unlimited supply of cigarettes tax-free. Paying such an upfront fee would require a mitment to the habit.

Although these examples are all monetarily based, other illustrations can be found of imposing self-constructed limits in order to increase awareness of choices. The Economist article mentions a program in Missouri that pulsive gamblers to add their names to a voluntary blacklist. If the gamblers breach the self-imposed ban by entering one of the state’s riverboat casinos, they face arrest for trespassing and the confiscation of their winnings.

Another example is covenant marriage laws that allow couples the freedom to choose to be held to a higher level of mitment. Before being able to obtain a divorce, spouses who entered into a covenant marriage limit the reasons they can seek a divorce and often must agree to undergo marital counseling before the marriage can be dissolved.

Although these examples are relatively benign, there is a danger in allowing government technocrats government influence the economic choices of affected parties in a way that will make choosers better off.

Several years ago, In a review of Robert and Edward Skidelsky’s book How Much is Enough?, Karen Horn explained why this approach often leads to disaster:

The Skidelskys produce a whole list of basic goods that constitute the good life as they see it: health, security, respect, personality (which in their view leads both to the right to a private sphere and to redistribution of property), friendship, leisure and harmony with nature. Not only are these items taken to be universal needs, but ends in themselves as well.

The argument is by no means religious. It is Aristotelian, based on a notion of natural law — and thus axiomatic. It is not a very large step from there to imposing a lifestyle on other people. Such intrusiveness cannot be avoided by paying lip-service to the idea of liberty. Calling one’s version of paternalism “non-coercive”, as the Skidelskys self-consciously rush to do, is not enough. These days, the “road to serfdom” that Friedrich Hayek famously feared to see Western civilisation embark on in the 1940s is paved with the good intentions of a fast-growing group of libertarian paternalists. And the self-appointed messiahs who show us the way along this road are clothed in nannies’ uniforms.

The policy mendations that flow from the Skidelskys are as old as they are proven recipes for disaster: ever more government influence, massive e redistribution, a basic wage, progressive consumer taxes, a slower economic integration of the world. Some ghosts continue to haunt us

Thaler would respond, as he did in his book Nudge, that, “The first misconception is that it is possible to avoid influencing people’s choices.”

If private and public institutions are going to attempt to influence people’s behavior (and they always will, say behavioral economists), why should they not do so in a way that, as Thaler and Sunstein claim, “steer people’s choices in directions that will improve their own welfare?” After all, as Thaler’s Nobel-winning research shows, humans are not the rational animals that economists have always presumed us to be. We are often willfully ignorant, intemperate, and prone to inertia. Libertarian paternalism offers a gentle correction, a non-intrusive means of influencing what another Nobel-winning economist, Thomas Schelling, calls the “intimate contest for mand.”

“Libertarian paternalism is a relatively weak, soft, and nonintrusive type of paternalism,” say Thaler and Sunstein, “because choices are not blocked, fenced off, or significantly burdened.” Are they right? Would we be better off trading the nanny state for the avuncular state?

Comments
Welcome to mreligion comments! Please keep conversations courteous and on-topic. To fosterproductive and respectful conversations, you may see comments from our Community Managers.
Sign up to post
Sort by
Show More Comments
RELIGION & LIBERTY ONLINE
Subsidiarity, Funding, and the Arts
In today’s edition of Capital Commentary, HBU assistant professor of literature Micah Mattix explores the question, “How Might the Arts Be Funded?” He ably and briefly surveys the recent history of politics surrounding the NEA. And he concludes by noting that art is inherently “relational” and that “the problem with large, centralized organizations like the Endowment is that they are often unable to take such relational elements into account.” He muses: However the arts are to be funded, this relational...
An End to Ethanol Subsidies?
With rising gas and food prices, ethanol subsidies are getting strict scrutiny. Many have called for the end of ethanol subsidies, and now the Senate is acting. Senators Tom Coburn and Dianne Feinstein introduced legislation that would end ethanol subsidies and repeal the tariff that is placed on foreign ethanol. The problems with ethanol subsidies have been vast as I’ve pointed out in previous posts including a tax credit for panies that blends ethanol with gasoline—even though they are mandated...
The Welfare State and the Moral High Ground
Writing in the Sacramento Bee, Margaret A. Bengs cites Rev. Robert A. Sirico’s Heritage Foundation essay “The Moral Basis for Economic Liberty” in her column on munities and government budget battles. As a priest, Sirico has met many entrepreneurs “who are disenfranchised and alienated from their churches,” with often little understanding by church leaders of the “vocation called entrepreneurship, of what it requires in the way of personal sacrifice, and of what it contributes to society.” This lack of understanding,...
Catholic Social Teaching and Capitalism
That’s the subject of my most recent article at . The new Crisis web site is a reinvigoration of the old Crisis magazine. Editor Brian Saint-Paul summarizes the history in his inaugural editorial. His statement of the vision of the new Crisis includes this: In the name of Catholic Social Thought, many in the Church continue to promote ideas of political economy that would hurt the very people they intend to help, and often do so with the suggestion that...
Survivors Not Victims
This video was captured by Toomer’s for Tuscaloosa at Five Points Baptist Church in Northport, Alabama. Northport is just outside Tuscaloosa. Toomer’s for Tuscaloosa has been leading from the front during the tornadoes that decimated parts of Alabama. Their Facebook page is mand center for leading and directing volunteers to areas of greatest need. ESPN highlighted some of the work of Toomer’s on their network. In a letter to Alabama Governor Robert Bentley, Toomer’s for Tuscaloosa wrote: In one way...
Rev. Sirico responds to Speaker Boehner’s Catholic Critics
On ...
Rising Food Prices and Regulation
In an article appearing on EWTN News, Acton Director of Research, Samuel Gregg, is interviewed on rising food prices and the effect on the developing world. In this article, Dr. Gregg contributed to a broad discussion on the many factors contributing to the rising food prices. He advocates for a free market economy in agriculture by discussing the effects agricultural subsides in Europe and the United State, and how these market distortions contribute to stifling the growth of agriculture in...
Film Spanks U.N. Treaty on the Rights of the Child
There’s a free screening of a documentary critiquing the U.N. Convention on the Rights of the Child this Friday evening at 7 p.m. at Grandville Church of Christ–3725 44th St. SW. The film makes the case that parental rights have already been dangerously eroded in the United States and would be further eroded if Congress ratified the U.N. treaty. The screening is sponsored by the area chapter of Generation Joshua and is open to the public. More against the treaty...
Stories from the Gulag
A new online exhibit: European Memories of the Gulag. (HT: Instapundit/Claire Berlinski) From 1939 to 1953, nearly one million people were deported to the Gulag from the European territories annexed by the USSR at the start of the Second World War and those that came under Soviet influence after the War: some to work camps but most as forced settlers in villages in Siberia and Central Asia. An international team of researchers has collected 160 statements from former deportees, photographs...
Acton on Tap: A Christian Economist Clarifies Fair Trade
The Acton Institute will be hosting another thought provoking and discussion orientated Acton on Tap on Tuesday, May 17. The event will begin at 6:30pm at the Derby Station (2237 Wealthy St. SE, East Grand Rapids 49506). Leading the discussion will be Victor Claar, who is a professor of Economics at Henderson State University. The Acton on Tap with Professor Claar is titled “Clarifying the Question of Fair Trade: A Christian Economist’s Perspective.” Claar will bring a unique perspective of...
Related Classification
Copyright 2023-2025 - www.mreligion.com All Rights Reserved