Home
/
RELIGION & LIBERTY ONLINE
/
Russ Roberts on Adam Smith and the limits of economics
Russ Roberts on Adam Smith and the limits of economics
Nov 10, 2024 3:48 PM

Russ Roberts — economist and host of the excellent EconTalk podcast — wrote a penetrating essay on what we can learn from Adam Smith’s first book, The Theory of Moral Sentiments.

According to Roberts,

[N]ot everything that is important can be quantified. I worry that as economists, we too often are like the drunk at 1 am looking for his keys under the glare of a streetlight. You go over to help and when you fail to find the keys you ask the drunk if he’s sure if he lost them here. Oh no, he responds. I’m not sure where I lost them. But the light’s better here.

While there are exceptions to this rule — Roberts himself being one of them — economists in general suffer a bit from this light’s-better-here problem, overlooking what can’t be quantified.

This is where Roberts thinks Smith can help:

Smith argues that we want the respect of those around us and we want to earn that respect honestly by how we actually behave rather than how we are perceived. We want our true self to be the source of our reputation. A single sentence sums up Smith’s view of our motivation:

Man naturally desires, not only to be loved, but to be lovely.

He continues,

Smith makes a bolder claim that this urge for respect from others is the source of our well-being. He writes:

… the chief part of human happiness arises from the consciousness of being beloved….

So consider the following. If Smith is right and if the the [sic] chief part of human happiness arises from the consciousness of being beloved, then what happens to people who are not beloved, not loved, not respected, not honored? What happens to people who no one pays attention to, people who struggle to find respect, honor, love? What happens to people who feel as if they do not matter?

With this question at the center, Roberts shows how policy-makers, whether conservative or progressive, too often fall into the light’s-better-here problem in the cases of mass shootings, minimum wages, and the opioid crisis. They argue over data and ignore the dignity of the persons at the center of these social problems. His reflection recalls for me how economic historian Ross Emmett has summarized Frank Knight’s view of the importance — and limits — of economics: “Life is economic; economics is not all of life.”

Paul Heyne warned of the danger of the light’s-better-here approach as well:

Such a rigid adherence to an untenable position severely restricts dialogue and inquiry and transforms suspicion into conviction for many who are beginning to wonder whether economics is not more ideology than science.

While I’m a bit more sympathetic to the possibility of value-free analysis, I wholeheartedly agree that to stop there puts economics in great peril. Only economists are content with considering economic questions apart from any moral foundation, framework, or context. The average person balks at such a thought experiment: the economy, the real-life one made up of actual people and their friends and families and neighbors and coworkers, doesn’t exist in a vacuum. It is a deep miscalculation to presume to address their struggles while bound to such limited parameters.

In their book When Helping Hurts, Steve Corbett and Brian Fikkert describe the contrast between the ways the poor across the world view themselves and the way in which middle class North Americans define poverty:

Poor people typically talk in terms of shame, inferiority, powerlessness, humiliation, fear, hopelessness, depression, social isolation, and voicelessness. North American audiences tend to emphasize a lack of material things such as food, money, clean water, medicine, housing, etc…. [T]his mismatch between many outsiders’ perceptions of poverty and the perceptions of poor people themselves can have devastating consequences for poverty-alleviation efforts.

In other words, not just economists but middle-class North Americans have a light’s-better-here problem too. They might not be modelling data, but they still over-focus on the material and measurable. Roberts points this out as well:

[E]conomists on the left and the right argue mostly about material well-being and most economists stay there under the streetlight because that’s where the data will always be best. So do non-economists. They use data like a cudgel to bludgeon the opposition, cherry-picking studies and facts to suit their story. The rest of the story, the part that can’t be quantified, is often ignored.

Roberts’ essay immediately reminded me of that quote from Corbet and Fikkert. It makes such a difference when we put “shame, inferiority, powerlessness, humiliation, fear, hopelessness, depression, social isolation, and voicelessness” in the center of our social discourse. It prevents us from always grasping for our preferred, patent, easy policy answer. It helps us see that while policy matters, policy is not all of life. Things like faith, family, and e into the foreground when the limited role of the material and measurable is put in its place. Another way to put it: life is material, but matter is not all of life.

Roberts concludes with an on-point biographical note about Smith:

Adam Smith never married. He had no children. Most of his life he lived with his mother.

But he was loved by not just his mother. He was respected and honored by the greatest minds and some of the most powerful people of the day — David Hume was his best friend. Smith was often alone. But he doesn’t seem to have been very lonely. He certainly was loved and lovely.

He only wrote two books in his lifetime, but oh the impact they’ve had. Together, they teach us something fundamental about what matters in this world. We would be wise to keep his wisdom close at hand when we think about public policy. We would be wise to remember the limits of looking only where the light is.

And, I would add, any reader would be wise to read Roberts’ full essay here.

Image credit: Adam Smith; engraving by John Kay

Update 3/29/2019: The quote from Adam Smith in the third block quote above has been corrected for accuracy from “… the consciousness of being loved” to “… the consciousness of being beloved.” Ellipses have also been added to indicate that the quote is part of a longer sentence. My thanks to Russ Roberts for alerting me to the error. – DJP

Comments
Welcome to mreligion comments! Please keep conversations courteous and on-topic. To fosterproductive and respectful conversations, you may see comments from our Community Managers.
Sign up to post
Sort by
Show More Comments
RELIGION & LIBERTY ONLINE
How marginal utility affects consumer choice
Note: This is post #69 in a weekly video series on basic microeconomics. When we buy a good or make a decision about how to use our time, we do so because we believe we are getting some sort of value from our choice, such as a sense of happiness or satisfaction. Economists call this “utility.” In this video by Marginal Revolution University, Joana Girante discusses the increase in the value from buying an additional unit of a good or...
The Oxfam scandal is about more than sex
Oxfam released its internal report on the Haiti scandal Monday, exposing that the controversy enveloping the agency was deeper and more expansive than previously known. In addition to the details already made public, the report states that allegations of fraud, negligence, sexual harassment, nepotism, and accessing pornography on an puter led to four firings and three resignations. The figure at the center of the controversy, Haitian country director Roland van Hauwermeiren, was allowed to make a “phased and dignified exit,”...
Radio Free Acton: Greg Forster on the legacy of Whittaker Chambers, Econ Quiz on income inequality, Upstream on Ursula K. Le Guin
On this episode of Radio Free Acton, Paul Bonicelli, director of programs and education at Acton, and Trey Dimsdale, director of program outreach at Acton, speak with Greg Forster, director of the Oikonomia Network and visiting assistant professor of faith and culture at Trinity International University, on the legacy and modern relevance of Whittaker Chambers and his landmark book,Witness. Then, Dave Hebert, professor of economics at Aquinas college, joins us on the Econ Quiz segment to talkabout e inequality. Finally,...
Oxfam’s ‘little gods’ exploit the poor
In a tragic irony, Oxfam has demonstrated the injustice of a certain kind of inequality. The international charity, which is known for its annual report on e inequality, is mired in scandal involving sexual coercion by its employees, possible pedophilia, and lying to a government agency in order to maintain taxpayer funding. While responding to the 2010 Haitian earthquake, relief workers engaged prostitutes in living quarters furnished by Oxfam, paid for with charitable donations (and tax dollars). Some have alleged...
Removing the scales: Peter Boettke on the public purpose of economics
Whenever a new economic policy is proposed or introduced, we are immediately confronted by a wave of pundits and pontificators, each offering their own spin on its real-world implications. Far too often, however, such analysis gives way to a flurry of passions: emotional, ideological, and otherwise. Which begs the question: What is the public purpose of the economist? According to economist Peter Boettke, it has to do with the illumination of truth, not only about market processes, but political processes,...
Rev. Sirico: What I learned from Michael Novak
Today is the first anniversary of the death of Michael Novak. The theologian, scholar, and writer was one of the most influential Catholic thinkers of his generation, and an indefatigable champion of free enterprise, democracy, and liberty. During his life Novak was a prolific writer. In addition to being the author or editor of more than 50 books, he wrote a syndicated column that was nominated for a Pulitzer. He was also a teacher (he taught at Harvard, Stanford, SUNY...
How entrepreneurship transforms a village
As we were walking down the street of a small village within Barahona in the Dominican Republic, we met a woman living in a humble home with her family. She had constructed a metal box out of scraps found discarded near her village, Algodon. On top of the box, she had a fire burning, and inside there was a large pan of yucca bread baking. It smelled delicious. This is precisely the type of person that the Acton Institute Poverty...
Video: Book Discussion on Kuyper and Islam
We’ve got video available of last week’s book launch discussion about Abraham Kuyper’s travels around the Mediterranean Sea. A portion of his travel record has been published as On Islam as part of the Abraham Kuyper Collected Works in Public Theology. James Bratt and Doug Howard, both of Calvin College and who edited the volume, were joined by the translator Jan van Vliet of Dordt College for a discussion which I moderated. Here’s the panel discussion: And the audience Q&A:...
Riding the net neutrality see-saw
This week, I was one of menters consulted in Nicholas Wolfram Smith’s article “FCC Repeal of Net Neutrality Leads to Lively Fight” for the National Catholic Register. I think Smith did a fine job conveying my primary concern: But according to Dylan Pahman, a researcher and managing editor of Acton Institute’s Journal of Markets & Morality, one of the problems with the 2015 net neutrality regulations was that it gave the government far too much regulatory power over ISPs. At...
Around the Old World-Sea
Later today we’re having a book launch discussion about the latest volume in the Abraham Kuyper Collected Works in Public Theology, On Islam. This book is a selection from a travel narrative Kuyper published after he voyaged around the Mediterranean Sea in 1905-1906. For those who are unable to join us in Grand Rapids, the event will be available via a live stream and will also be archived for viewing later. For those interested in learning more about Kuyper’s trip,...
Related Classification
Copyright 2023-2024 - www.mreligion.com All Rights Reserved