Home
/
RELIGION & LIBERTY ONLINE
/
Public Discourse: Rethinking Economics in the Post-Crisis World
Public Discourse: Rethinking Economics in the Post-Crisis World
Oct 9, 2024 7:21 PM

The Public Discourse recently published my article, Rethinking Economics in the Post-Crisis World. Text follows:

In the wake of the financial crisis, we need an economics with greater humility about its predictive power and an increased understanding of plicated human beings who, when the discipline is rightly understood, lie at its center.

Apart from bankers and politicians, few groups have received as much blame for the 2008 financial crisis as economists. “Economists are the forgotten guilty men” was how Anatole Kaletsky, former economics editor and current editor-at-large for the London Times, put it earlier this year when explaining why “a bank with just $1 billion of capital [would] borrow an extra $99 billion and then buy $100 billion of speculative investments.”

Greed and sheer imprudence played a role, but so too, Kaletsky argued, did those (unnamed) economists who posited that their models proved that events such as the collapse of Lehmann Brothers in 2008 or Long Term Capital Management in 1998 were mathematically likely to happen once every billion years.

Kaletsky’s broader point was that contemporary mainstream economics had been sufficiently discredited by the financial crisis that the entire discipline required what he called an “intellectual revolution,” or it risked being dismissed as a rather suspect sub-branch of statistical analysis and mathematical modeling.

Kaletsky is hardly alone in arguing that economists need to rethink key aspects of their discipline. Though unwilling to call for a total paradigm shift, the Economist recently opined that the financial crisis has raised profound questions of coherence about two areas of economics: macro-economics and financial economics. “Few financial economists,” the Economist observed, “thought much about illiquidity or counterparty risk, for instance, because their standard models ignore it.” Likewise, the mented, “Macroeconomists also had a blindspot: their standard models assumed that capital markets work perfectly.”

All this is certainly true. But the key expression to note here is “their standard models.”

Since John Maynard Keynes’s time, mainstream economics has undergone a steady process of mathematization. Anyone doubting this need only peruse their nearest copy of the American Economic Review and observe the plethora of algebra, mathematics, and abstract modeling that is central to most mainstream economists’ argumentation—regardless of whether they mitted neo-Keynesians or proponents of the efficient markets hypothesis.

Of course there is, as Nobel Prize economist Myron Scholes notes, a difference between the academic economists creating the models and the Wall Street financial engineers applying these models in the marketplace. Indeed many economists who support the efficient market hypothesis have introduced numerous qualifications—based, for example, on their willingness to import insights from other disciplines—to explain apparently irrational economic behavior by individuals and institutions.

Much of this work will bear fruit over time. It is telling, however, that there appears to be little inclination on the part of some contemporary economists to ask some searching questions about their heavy reliance on mathematical logic and argumentation. This may well be because doing so would raise some rather profound questions about the very nature of post-Keynesian economic science.

One who posed precisely these questions was the German economist Wilhelm Röpke (1899-1966). Röpke is well-known as an intellectual architect of post-war West Germany’s path from collectivist economic oblivion to market-driven economic miracle in the ten years following its economic liberalization in 1948.

Less attention, however, has been given to Röpke’s fierce critiques of the post-war Keynesian consensus. On one level, this was driven by Röpke’s belief that Keynesian policies would inexorably reduce political and economic freedom. But another source of Röpke’s angst was his conviction that Keynes and his disciples had corrupted economics as a social science.

In Röpke’s view, Keynes was “a representative of the geometric spirit of the 20th century” and “an exponent of positivistic scientism,” for whom “economics was part of a mathematical-mechanical universe.” While Röpke assigned more blame to Keynes’s disciples, he insisted that Keynes’s approach to economics had created an “old economics” and a “new economics” in which the sense of one was nonsense in the other.

According to Röpke, the neo-Keynesian new economics was inclined to reduce economics to mathematical and statistical formulas and analyses. Röpke may have been thinking of Paul Samuelson’s 1947 effort to reconfigure economics on the basis of mathematical language. For Röpke, such efforts conflated the object of economics with one tool of economic analysis. Opening a post-Keynes economic textbook, Röpke suggested, made readers wonder if they had stumbled upon a chemistry curriculum.

Mathematics is a form of language based upon symbols. Its origins lie in facilitating the study of the natural sciences. But mathematics is less adequate when es to analyzing things which are unquestionably real and have implications for economic life such as traditions, institutions, and values. Röpke believed that mathematical formalism addressed these realities by generally ignoring them. Economics thus became a quantitative exercise that “teems with equations in ever-increasing profusion” and focused upon developing models and patterns of aggregate behavior by whole populations.

While accepting that the new economics enhanced the use of macroeconomic concepts, plained that Keynes had effectively “declared the method of thinking in aggregates to be the only one, both now and in the long run.” Economics consequently lost sight of its essence which is not macro-aggregates but the choices of individuals and institutions. On this basis, Röpke believed that the “new economics” was destroying economics as “a ‘moral science’ in the sense that it deals with man as an intellectual and moral being.”

In Röpke’s view, sound economics certainly allows the use of mathematics to explain certain relationships that have quantitative characteristics. Nevertheless the more economics drifted in a mathematical-statistical direction, the less attention it paid to that which is un-mathematical and which does not always behave predictably—human beings. Though Röpke believed that mathematics can help describe relatively stable and plicated economic relationships, he was unconvinced it could handle the plexity and instability of actual economic life. The eventual result, Röpke stated, was not only that “with all our cleverness, we have e decidedly less wise, while knowing more and more about less and less,” but also the “dehumanization of economic science.”

Worries about these developments were not confined to convinced free marketers. One of Keynes’s earliest followers and first biographer, Sir Roy mented that many economists’ effective replacement of attention to basic economic principles with an immersion in mathematics and aggregates had led him to conclude that “we should be better off with the old political economy.”

Reflecting upon the expression political economy might not be a bad place to start for those interested in rethinking economics’ foundations in a post-crisis era. In Adam Smith’s Wealth of Nations, the term acquires three meanings.

The first is monly accepted positive sense of political economy as the scientific study of “the nature and causes of the wealth of nations.” More broadly, however, Smith’s political economy also embraces the study of the interrelationship between economic theory and the political ideas and movements of a given time. Lastly, there is the sense in which Smith understood political economy in terms of what we today call economic policy: “a branch of the science of the statesman or legislator” whose objective was “more properly to enable [people] to provide such a revenue or subsistence for themselves; and . . . to supply the state monwealth with a revenue sufficient to the public services.”

On one level, the Wealth of Nations does involve abstract analysis of economic life. Smith carefully dissects the claims of prevailing economic thought, presents a fresh theory about how wealth is created, and elaborates on what should be done in policy-terms if wealth creation and society’s overall material enrichment are deemed desirable. But in doing so Smith also attempts to develop a powerful normative argument for an economy based around private property, petition, and limited government over and against the mercantilist systems that dominated eighteenth-century Europe.

As the economic historian Emma Rothschild reminds us, Smith sees economic liberty as something to be approved and pursued partly because of its capacity to liberate people from many forms of oppression. For Smith, the move from mercantilist to market economies was not only a matter of following the promptings of scientific economic reasoning focused on wealth-creation. Smith also regards market economies as superior to previous economic arrangements on grounds of the greater efficiency and liberty they accorded to ever-widening numbers of people to seek human fulfillment.

Unfortunately, with some notable exceptions, this Smithian conception of political economy did not persist after Smith’s death in 1790. By John Stuart Mill’s time, political economy was being defined as studying the behavior of homo economicus, a creature whose nature is far removed from that of the plex, not-always rational being found in Smith’s writings. From here, it was only a short step towards the reduction of much economics to a branch of applied mathematics, however valiantly this trend has been resisted by the Austrian and Public Choice schools.

Obviously there are many aspects and tools of modern economics with which we would not want to do without. But a renewed focus upon political economy in Smith’s three senses might provide a rich starting point for economists interested in the deep rethinking advocated by Kaletsky. It would maintain economics’ strong empirical-positive dimension, but blend it with a deeper appreciation for plexity, and thus engender more humility about economics’ predictive power—a virtue all of us could use more of in our post-crisis era.

Comments
Welcome to mreligion comments! Please keep conversations courteous and on-topic. To fosterproductive and respectful conversations, you may see comments from our Community Managers.
Sign up to post
Sort by
Show More Comments
RELIGION & LIBERTY ONLINE
Once Again, Religious Shareholder Activists Fail Massively
Despite what is heralded as a banner year for proxy resolutions submitted by religious shareholder activists As You Sow and the Interfaith Center on Corporate Responsibility, 2014 was anything but. Even the left-leaning Center for Political Accountability reports most so-called shareholder victories for political spending disclosure were performed panies’ own initiative rather than prompted by resolutions authored by CPA and submitted by activist shareholders under the guise of religious principles. The AYS and ICCR narrative collapses further under scrutiny from...
Sober and Courageous: Tim Keller on Risk in the Christian Life
The Christian life is one filled with risk, driven by active faith in an active God whose ways are higher than our own. In all that we put our hands to, God calls us to turn away from the supposed predictability of our own plans and designs and rely entirelyon Him. Such an orientation transforms each area of our lives, from family and friends to politics to church life and beyond. But for those involved in entrepreneurship and business, the...
The Endangered Family And Why It Must Be Saved
It’s easy to say that a “family can be anything you choose.” You can have Molly has two mommies, or Jaxon who splits his time between Dad’s house and Mom’s or some version of “his, mine, ours.” In reality, the traditional family is a necessary economic and sociological element of a strong society. It’s like the game Jenga: you can slide and maneuver things all you want, but eventually, it es crashing down. Jonathan V. Last, writing at The Weekly...
Preventing Human Trafficking
Human trafficking can be prevented. It takes tenacity, hard work, and knowledge of the needs of the people in a particular area of the world. One of the greatest “push” factors (those factors that drive people into human trafficking) is poverty. Poverty creates desperation, and desperation drives trafficking. Parents cannot afford to feed children, and will sell them off. Sometimes people are tricked, thinking that their child will be given a job or education. Women will sell their bodies because...
Audio: Paul Edwards Hosts West Michigan Live on WOOD Radio
Mako Fujimura Acton broadcast consultant, Paul Edwards, took over the WOOD Radio microphone this morning to guest-host West Michigan Live here in in Grand Rapids. He covered a range of topics over the course of his broadcast hour, and spoke with artist Makoto Fujimura, whose 2014 ArtPrize entry, Walking on Water, was exhibited at the Acton Building. Their conversation focused on this piece, written by Mako, on his experience at ArtPrize and how petition does – and does not –...
Acton On WOOD Radio With Mako Fujimura
Acton broadcast consultant, Paul Edwards, will guest host West Michigan Live on Tuesday, October 21 at 9:00 am EST on WOOD Radio in Grand Rapids. His guest at 9:30 a.m. is artist Makoto Fujimura, whose 2014 ArtPrize entry, Walking on Water, was exhibited at the Acton Building. At his blog, Mako has written an engaging and thoughtful piece about his experience at ArtPrize which will be the focus of Paul’s conversation with him. In West Michigan, you can listen live...
Religion & Liberty: Interview with Makoto Fujimura
In a mencement address at Messiah College in Pennsylvania, Makoto Fujimura told the graduating class, “We are to rise above the darkened realities, the confounding problems of our time.” A tall order for any age, but one God has decisively e in Jesus Christ. Fujimura uses his talent to connect beauty with the truth of the Gospel in a culture that has largely forgotten its religious tradition and history. He makes those things fresh and visible again. With works like...
Radio Free Acton: The Global Vatican, Part 2
On this week’s edition of Radio Free Acton, we bring you part two of Michael Matheson Miller’s conversation with Ambassador Francis Rooney, who served as U.S. Ambassador to the Holy See from 2005 to 2008 under President George W. Bush. Rooney has a new book out on the Vatican’s role in the world entitledThe Global Vatican.Miller and Rooney discuss the soft-power global role of the Vatican, and the relationship between the Vatican and the United Nations, which has been rocky...
How an Innovative Coat Designer is Helping the Homeless
As a 20 year old product design student, Veronika Scott developed an innovative coat/sleeping-bag for the homeless. But one day when she was giving the coats away, a woman came out of a homeless shelter and told her, “We don’t need coats, coats are pointless. We need jobs.” Scott realized the woman was right. So she found a way to provide temporary help and still make a lasting change in people’s lives. ...
Why Can’t We Get Wasted Food to the Hungry?
In your kitchen right now is food that is going to be wasted. Although it may still be sitting in your pantry or in your refrigerator, you’ll eventually throw it away. Milk and cheese will go bad before you finish it, bread will get stale and moldy, and the can of kale will go in the trash as soon as you remember you bought a can of kale (seriously, what were you thinking?). That Americans waste a lot of food...
Related Classification
Copyright 2023-2024 - www.mreligion.com All Rights Reserved