Home
/
RELIGION & LIBERTY
/
Preventing Regulation by Enforcement
Preventing Regulation by Enforcement
Apr 8, 2025 8:33 PM

  America prides itself on being a land where individuals and businesses can plan their futures. Control over the design of your life is essential to liberty, and the nation prospers when people know that their enterprises and investments will be immune from arbitrary enforcement. However, in a world of wide-ranging regulations—covering everything from cryptocurrency markets to healthcare to environmental standards—the promise of legal predictability often goes unfulfilled. Many agencies, instead of clearly stating the rules in advance, prefer to announce them during an enforcement action. This approach, known as “regulation by enforcement,” stifles innovation, chokes off economic growth, and undermines the rule of law.

  Regulation by enforcement has become a flashpoint. Last month, Judge Stephano Bibas of the Third Circuit Court of Appeals noted: “Nearly a century ago, Congress created the SEC to serve as a watchdog for securities markets, including by developing rules. The SEC insists that its old rules apply to the novel crypto market but refuses to spell out how.” He then opined:

  Crypto companies like Coinbase are confused about how to comply with the law and have repeatedly asked the SEC to clarify. Instead of doing so, the SEC sues the companies individually. It wants to proceed with ex post enforcement without announcing ex ante rules or guidance. … Its old regulations fit poorly with this new technology, and its enforcement strategy raises constitutional notice concerns.

  In a recent article, we show that there is a statutory tool, as old as modern administrative law itself, admirably adapted to combat these ills. Section 5(d) of the Administrative Procedure Act (APA) commands government agencies to issue “declaratoryorders” to clarify the legal status of regulated conduct before the regulated party faces adverse consequences. Adeclaratoryorder is a binding, noncoercive ruling that definitively declares whether a proposed or ongoing activity complies with the law. If it sounds too good to be true for regulated persons, that might explain why agencies have resisted it—after all, bureaucrats often seize the advantage over ordinary citizens by maintaining maximum flexibility. But by ignoring or underusingdeclaratoryorders for decades, agencies have frustrated Congress’s original vision. Restoring that vision can foster economic growth and revive key rule-of-law values in our administrative state.

  The Dangers of Regulation by Enforcement

  No one disputes that government has a significant role in protecting the public and correcting market failures. However, the regulatory apparatus can become dangerous when agencies rely too heavily on enforcement actions to clarify what the law demands. Instead of laying out clear rules, agencies may wait until a business moves forward with a new product, practice, or service. Then, if the agency disapproves, it slaps the business with sanctions, fines, or other penalties.

  This approach deprives citizens of fair notice. An innovative firm might invest years of effort and millions of dollars only to discover that its innovative product is outlawed by some unannounced bureaucratic interpretation. The blunt force of enforcement then chills the next wave of innovation.

  The Original Meaning of Section 5(d)

  Courts are beginning to pay more attention to the original meaning of the Administrative Procedure Act (APA), just as they have with the Constitution. This would be another good case for applying originalism. In 1946, to reconcile the rule of law with administrative power, Congress enacted the APA. The APA established a rule-of-law foundation for the regulatory state. One of the Act’s neglected provisions is Section 5(d), authorizing—and indeed requiring in some circumstances—agencies to issuedeclaratoryorders “to terminate a controversy or remove uncertainty” in matters that fall under their authority. The basic idea is straightforward: rather than forcing a regulated party to guess whether they comply with a host of complex rules, the firm can ask the relevant agency for a formal, binding answer ahead of time. If the agency issues adeclaratoryorder approving the proposed activity, the business can proceed in confidence. If the agency issues an unfavorable order, the business knows whether to change its plan or seek a change in the regulatory framework.

  Unfortunately, even though the APA’s language is quite plain—an agency “in its sound discretion … may issue a declaratory order”—few agencies have embraced the device in any robust way. It is true that they sometimes opt for nonbinding “advisory opinions” or “no-action letters” that offer no guaranteed security.” But these mechanisms leave room for the agency to reverse course—without notice. By contrast, a proper declaratory order binds the agency, subject, of course, to valid reasons for revisiting the ruling in the future, and provides legal certainty so businesses can plan accordingly.

  Mandating the broader use ofdeclaratoryorders would not only implement faithfully Congress’s directive but would also restore confidence and creativity in our commercial republic.

  One might ask why agencies are not free to refuse declaratory orders whenever they want. After all, the APA’s text states that the agency “may” issue adeclaratoryorder. Yet that same sentence also invokes the phrase “in its sound discretion”—the only time the phrase is used in the APA. “Sound discretion” was a legal term of art in 1946. At that time, “sound discretion” in the courts meant equitable, reviewable discretion: judges could not arbitrarily refuse to issue adeclaratoryjudgment if the facts were concrete and issuing that ruling would “remove uncertainty or terminate a controversy.” This limited kind of discretion required a genuine balancing of interests. No court has ever taken the position that an agency’s decision whether to issue a declaratory order is dependent on its whim. But courts have yet to understand the robustness of the sound discretion standard.

  Congress borrowed that standard from judicialdeclaratoryjudgments and embedded it in the APA, intending for agencies to follow suit. At the time of enactment, the judiciary was required to provide a declaratory order whenever a party faced actual harm, unless there was a good reason not to. Similarly, in administrative procedure, where a regulated party faces real risk from an unclear rule, the agency must either give an answer or provide a good reason for refusing. Fear of additional costs or inconvenience to the agency does not, by itself, trump Congress’s command. Indeed, the APA specifically authorizes agencies to charge filing fees fordeclaratoryorders, so that resource concerns need never become an excuse for refusing them.

  Moreover, agencies remain free to deny or postpone adeclaratoryorder when someone brings a frivolous request or when key facts are still in flux. If the question is purely hypothetical or if the relevant law will be examined in a pending enforcement matter already underway, the agency has latitude not to issue the order. But absent such legitimate grounds, a refusal to provide clarity undermines both liberty and the rule of law.

  Declaratory Orders After Chevron

  By its terms, section 5(d) applies only to formal adjudication, and much agency adjudication is informal. But the Supreme Court precedent, followed by lower courts, has applied section 5(d) to informal adjudication as well. Thus, statutory stare decisis supports this broader scope even if it was wrong as an original matter.

  Moreover, even if the Supreme Court revisited the scope of declaratory orders and narrowed its ambit to formal adjudications, more agency adjudication is likely to become formal after Chevron’s demise. Chevron permitted agencies to interpret in favor of informality any ambiguity about whether they were required to hold formal hearings. Given the greater ease of informal procedures, some agencies exploited ambiguity in just that way. But now, post-Chevron courts must decide whether a statute mandates formal or informal hearings for the agency. Courts, as neutral arbiters that are intimately familiar with process, are likely to interpret statutes as providing regulated parties with the more ample procedures of formal adjudication.

  In any event, the new administration could itself reinvigorate declaratory orders. First, it could order agencies to follow the original meaning of “sound discretion” in section 5(d). Second, it could go even further than Congresss command and tell agencies to provide declaratory orders whenever they are not forbidden by law, and the public benefit outweighs the administrative cost. Agencies have substantial discretion to provide more process than the APA requires them to provide. This executive order would comport with the superb administrative approach adopted by the first Trump administration, which tried to make it easier for citizens and companies to plan. For example, the administration required all agency guidance to be publicly available. An executive order on declaratory orders would provide another boon to planning and therefore to liberty.

  The Payoff of Declaratory Orders

  Consider the present-day scenario of a firm hoping to list a novel cryptocurrency exchange-traded fund (ETF). As highlighted last month by Judge Bibas, such products exist at the forefront of both technology and finance, creating uncertainty about how they fit within longstanding securities rules. Multiple companies have tried to get approval for these crypto-related funds, but regulators have been hesitant or slow to act.

  Adeclaratoryorder from the SEC, by contrast, would provide definitive clarity on whether the specific structure of the proposed ETF complies with the rules. If yes, the firm can proceed confidently, attracting investors and encouraging broader market development. If not, the firm knows that it must modify its approach or seek a different path. In both cases, the free market benefits from clear signals on how to innovate in a lawful manner.

  The same reasoning applies across the regulatory spectrum. Think of environmental permitting: a company wants to deploy modern technologies to reduce emissions, but it is not entirely sure whether those new processes meet the Clean Air Act’s requirements. Or think of telehealth platforms that leverage advanced software for patient care but remain unsure if certain privacy protocols meet federal health regulations. In each case, adeclaratoryorder could provide certainty and thus encourage innovation.

  Declaratoryorders, properly applied, reflect the “better angels” of our administrative system. They turn agencies into partners who, far from threatening enforcement at every turn, share their expertise upfront. Citizens do not fear investing in the latest ideas because they know they can rely on the agency’s declared position—subject, of course, to any genuinely new developments that might require reevaluation.

  We prosper when entrepreneurs can engage in a dynamic marketplace governed by sensible, consistent rules. Yet we need regulations to prevent companies from wrongly imposing costs and dangers on our citizens. One overlooked but important mechanism permits bold enterprise and necessary regulation to flourish together. That mechanism lies in the original understanding of the APA, in a provision enacted by Congress to afford private actors the ability to force answers from agencies. Mandating the broader use ofdeclaratoryorders would not only implement faithfully Congress’s directive but would also restore confidence and creativity in our commercial republic.

Comments
Welcome to mreligion comments! Please keep conversations courteous and on-topic. To fosterproductive and respectful conversations, you may see comments from our Community Managers.
Sign up to post
Sort by
Show More Comments
RELIGION & LIBERTY
Adam Smith and the Poor
Adam Smith did not seem to think that riches were requisite to happiness: “the beggar, who suns himself by the side of the highway, possesses that security which kings are fighting for” (The Theory of Moral Sentiments). But he did not mend beggary. The beggar here is not any beggar, but Diogenes the Cynic, who asked of Alexander the Great only to step back so as not to cast a shadow upon Diogenes as he reclined alongside the highway....
Lord Jonathan Sacks: The West’s Rabbi
In October 1798, the president of the United States wrote to officers of the Massachusetts militia, acknowledging a limitation of federal rule. “We have no government,” John Adams wrote, “armed with power capable of contending with human passions unbridled by morality and religion. Avarice, ambition, and revenge or gallantry, would break the strongest cords of our Constitution as a whale goes through a net.” The nation that Adams had helped to found would require the parts of the body...
How Dispensationalism Got Left Behind
Whether we like it or not, Americans, in one way or another, have all been indelibly shaped by dispensationalism. Such is the subtext of Daniel Hummel’s provocative telling of the rise and fall of dispensationalism in America. In a little less than 350 pages, Hummel traces how a relatively insignificant Irishman from the Plymouth Brethren, John Nelson Darby, prompted the proliferation of dispensational theology, especially its eschatology, or theology of the end times, among our ecclesiastical, cultural, and political...
Conversation Starters with … Anne Bradley
Anne Bradley is an Acton affiliate scholar, the vice president of academic affairs at The Fund for American Studies, and professor of economics at The Institute of World Politics. There’s much talk about mon good capitalism” these days, especially from the New Right. Is this long overdue, that a hyper-individualism be beaten back, or is it merely cover for increasing state control of the economy? Let me begin by saying that I hate “capitalism with adjectives” in general. This...
Mistaken About Poverty
Perhaps it is because America is the land of liberty and opportunity that debates about poverty are especially intense in the United States. Americans and would-be Americans have long been told that if they work hard enough and persevere they can achieve their dreams. For many people, the mere existence of poverty—absolute or relative—raises doubts about that promise and the American experiment more generally. Is it true that America suffers more poverty than any other advanced democracy in the...
Spurgeon and the Poverty-Fighting Church
Religion & Liberty: Volume 33, Number 4 Spurgeon and the Poverty-Fighting Church by Christopher Parr • October 30, 2023 Portrait of Charles Spurgeon by Alexander Melville (1885) Charles Spurgeon was a young, zealous 15-year-old boy when he came to faith in Christ. A letter to his mother at the time captures the enthusiasm of his newfound Christian faith: “Oh, how I wish that I could do something for Christ.” God granted that wish, as Spurgeon would e “the prince of...
Up from the Liberal Founding
During the 20th century, scholars of the American founding generally believed that it was liberal. Specifically, they saw the founding as rooted in the political thought of 17th-century English philosopher John Locke. In addition, they saw Locke as a primarily secular thinker, one who sought to isolate the role of religion from political considerations except when necessary to prop up the various assumptions he made for natural rights. These included a divine creator responsible for a rational world for...
C.S. Lewis and the Apocalypse of Gender
From very nearly the beginning, Christianity has wrestled with the question of the body. Heretics from gnostics to docetists devalued physical reality and the body, while orthodox Christianity insisted that the physical world offers us true signs pointing to God. This quarrel persists today, and one form it takes is the general confusion among Christians and non-Christians alike about gender. Is gender an abstracted idea? Is it reducible to biological characteristics? Is it a set of behaviors determined by...
Creating an Economy of Inclusion
The poor have been the main subject of concern in the whole tradition of Catholic Social Teaching. The Catholic Church talks often about a “preferential option for the poor.” In recent years, many of the Church’s social teaching documents have been particularly focused on the needs of the poorest people in the world’s poorest countries. The first major analysis of this topic could be said to have been in the papal encyclical Populorum Progressio, published in 1967 by Pope...
Jesus and Class Warfare
Plenty of Marxists have turned to the New Testament and the origins of Christianity. Memorable examples include the works of F.D. Maurice and Zhu Weizhi’s Jesus the Proletarian. After criticizing how so many translations of the New Testament soften Jesus’ teachings regarding material possessions, greed, and wealth, Orthodox theologian David Bentley Hart has gone so far to ask, “Are Christians supposed to be Communists?” In the Huffington Post, Dan Arel has even claimed that “Jesus was clearly a Marxist,...
Related Classification
Copyright 2023-2025 - www.mreligion.com All Rights Reserved