Home
/
RELIGION & LIBERTY
/
Learning from Preventable Tragedy
Learning from Preventable Tragedy
Sep 7, 2024 11:30 PM

  I was born in Porto Alegre, Brazil. Porto Alegre is in front of Lake Guaiba, which is formed by five rivers. In 1941, it suffered a tragic flood. Lake Guaiba rose almost sixteen feet above average, and a quarter of the population lost their homes. The trauma of such an event led the federal, state, and local governments to build dikes, walls, and pump systems to protect the city from a “once-in-a-hundred-year event.” According to the estimate, dikes and walls twenty feet tall would offer such protection.

  Since 1941, there have been many other storms and floods, but the investments, which I would guess are in the ballpark of one billion dollars, were sufficient to prevent significant damage until two weeks ago. In early May 2024, torrential rains raised the Guaiba waters to a record of eighteen feet. The floods upstream and in the Guaiba Lake killed hundreds, left more than six hundred thousand homeless, and destroyed infrastructure and other capital goods statewide.

  In Porto Alegre, the flood protection system failed miserably; one-third of the city is underwater, the airport is closed indefinitely, and the town was left with just one land connection with the rest of the country. Two weeks after all this started, the distribution of water and electricity has not yet returned to most of the city, and tens of thousands are homeless.

  Why did the flood protection measures fail? There are many different reasons, but in the big picture, misaligned incentives within government led to catastrophic failure and tragedy. We do not yet know the full extent of the tragedy, but in hindsight, it seems evident that the tragedy was to be expected.

  In the aftermath of the 1941 disaster, there was a sense of urgency about addressing the problem and preventing another such tragedy. That contributed to the lobbying power of construction companies, enabling the system to be built. Unfortunately, over time, the memory of the 1941 flood was lost. No longer pressed by any powerful lobby, the city counselors neglected to adequately fund the upkeep of the dikes, walls, and pumping stations.

  For a time, civil servants were still officially in charge of that service, even though their budget was inadequate. Then a too-clever-by-half mayor proposed abolishing the department in charge of the system’s upkeep, transferring its attributions to the entity that produces and distributes potable water in the city and maintains the sewage, drainage, and, from that moment on, also flood prevention. It sounded to him like a good idea because that public-owned utility is funded with a fee on water consumption. Instead of maintaining the flood protection system through taxes duly voted by the city council, they could be funded through a cross-subsidy. Out of view, out of mind, the necessary investments were not made, and the system quietly eroded. But everybody was happy until tragedy struck, and people started to ask how that happened.

  Porto Alegre has two-thirds of the city area zoned for agriculture or nature preserves, which makes it out of bounds for urban development. This means low-income people have no alternative but to remain in the floodplain. 

  What has just happened in Porto Alegre may serve as a cautionary tale about the many ways collective action may go awry. No politician simply decided to build a faulty flood prevention system, or to allow the existing one to decay. Butthe incentives to design and build a sound system, in keeping with the criteria defined in the original study, were not there. Indeed, insofar as proper designcosts money, both contractors and politicians had strong incentives to cut corners. Inspectors were not always aware of technical reasons for some requirements, and just in general, few people were paying attention. The situation with the maintenance is even more tragic. It was entirely predictable that leaving such an important matter to a minor office with other responsibilities, to be funded by a hidden charge on the water bills, would prove a recipe for a serious breakdown in the system.

  If this is an accurate interpretation of the events, what lessons of universal value can we draw from them?

  The mistakes that led to the failure in this case, combined with broader reflections on human behavior, can point towards better principles for public governance. These principles must be informed by much more than the narrow events described above. They need to consider reflections on proper human behavior.

  One interesting way of approaching the problem is by considering how one might go about rebuilding Porto Alegre. To answer that question, we need to consider which would be more economical: rebuilding in the same places where the damaged buildings once stood, with effective protective measures, or rebuilding elsewhere and leaving the low areas for temporary uses such as parks.

  Here we encounter a truly problematic epistemological question. I doubt anyone can know how to calculate this if we do not put a “price” on building on a floodplain. There are many ways to do that. An obvious one is to require anyone with a house, a shop, or a warehouse built on a floodplain to buy flood insurance in the private market. That seems a good way to put a “price” on such a decision. Any American living in a floodplain knows this, despite the distortions created when flood insurance in the US was nationalized.

  Next, let us consider which principles should inform the ways to fund whatever protection against floods should exist. Here another problem becomes evident: the flood protection system was treated as a public good. This largely explains the misaligned incentives discussed above. If the local government farmed out the service to private companies, who were compensated by a fee charged to the residents and businesses of the protected areas, it is far more likely that building and maintenance would be done properly. This is so precisely because flood protection is not a true public good; that is, its benefit is not diffused; it can be measured, the beneficiaries identified, and a price charged for its provision. That is the lesson of universal application.

  The less efficient the protection those companies provide, the more expensive the premiums to pay for the flood insurance, and vice versa. So, the residents and businesses of the protected areas will be financially incentivized to demand that local government collaborate with efficient companies to provide those services.

  The design of these arrangements I have in mind is similar to the ones used for trash collection, with the difference that the residents and businesses do not pay a monetary penalty for failing to demand efficient trash collection, as they would under the proposed system in the form of the flood insurance premiums.

  I have no idea if people under these conditions would move to areas with higher elevations. Presumably, they would weigh the cost of remaining in their previous locations against the cost of developed land in higher elevations, which varies significantly from place to place. Porto Alegre, for instance, has two-thirds of the city area zoned for agriculture or nature preserves, which makes it out of bounds for urban development. This often means that low-income people have no alternative but to remain in the floodplain. Revising the zoning laws could open other options for them.

  That points to yet another problem of collective action. As the researchers of the ILD in Peru concluded many years ago, the cost of operating in the “formal” sector determines the size of the “informal” sector. That is a simple application of the logic of thinking at the margin. The same sorts of calculations affect people’s decision whether to live in a floodplain near the existing jobs and urban infrastructure, or on a highland far from everything. If there are “artificial” (legal) barriers to developing certain lands for urban use, people may make choices that would otherwise be imprudent or just inefficient.

  All of this changes if people pay the real costs of private goods that, at first glance, look like public goods. In this case, instead of paying for flood protection with taxes collected from people not directly affected by the flooding, they could have charged the beneficiaries of such infrastructure more directly. This would not only solve the problem of economic allocation, but would do so in the fairest mode possible.

  Some may complain that I lack compassion with the unfortunate flood victims. I disagree, but this is not the place to argue about that. I will say that hard cases make bad laws. Here is yet another lesson that should inform our views of collective action: solutions that are needed in emergencies should notrule society in normal times.

  Rebuilding from tragedies like the one that just happened in my hometown, as efficiently and reasonably as possible, will require a decision to internalize the price of people’s decisions about where to live and work. This will create incentives for proper investments in flood prevention. As in any other case of collective action, the solution lies in expanding people’s freedom, and expecting them to pay the real costs for what they want.

Comments
Welcome to mreligion comments! Please keep conversations courteous and on-topic. To fosterproductive and respectful conversations, you may see comments from our Community Managers.
Sign up to post
Sort by
Show More Comments
RELIGION & LIBERTY
Conversation Starters with … Anne Bradley
Anne Bradley is an Acton affiliate scholar, the vice president of academic affairs at The Fund for American Studies, and professor of economics at The Institute of World Politics. There’s much talk about mon good capitalism” these days, especially from the New Right. Is this long overdue, that a hyper-individualism be beaten back, or is it merely cover for increasing state control of the economy? Let me begin by saying that I hate “capitalism with adjectives” in general. This...
Up from the Liberal Founding
During the 20th century, scholars of the American founding generally believed that it was liberal. Specifically, they saw the founding as rooted in the political thought of 17th-century English philosopher John Locke. In addition, they saw Locke as a primarily secular thinker, one who sought to isolate the role of religion from political considerations except when necessary to prop up the various assumptions he made for natural rights. These included a divine creator responsible for a rational world for...
Adam Smith and the Poor
Adam Smith did not seem to think that riches were requisite to happiness: “the beggar, who suns himself by the side of the highway, possesses that security which kings are fighting for” (The Theory of Moral Sentiments). But he did not mend beggary. The beggar here is not any beggar, but Diogenes the Cynic, who asked of Alexander the Great only to step back so as not to cast a shadow upon Diogenes as he reclined alongside the highway....
Spurgeon and the Poverty-Fighting Church
Religion & Liberty: Volume 33, Number 4 Spurgeon and the Poverty-Fighting Church by Christopher Parr • October 30, 2023 Portrait of Charles Spurgeon by Alexander Melville (1885) Charles Spurgeon was a young, zealous 15-year-old boy when he came to faith in Christ. A letter to his mother at the time captures the enthusiasm of his newfound Christian faith: “Oh, how I wish that I could do something for Christ.” God granted that wish, as Spurgeon would e “the prince of...
C.S. Lewis and the Apocalypse of Gender
From very nearly the beginning, Christianity has wrestled with the question of the body. Heretics from gnostics to docetists devalued physical reality and the body, while orthodox Christianity insisted that the physical world offers us true signs pointing to God. This quarrel persists today, and one form it takes is the general confusion among Christians and non-Christians alike about gender. Is gender an abstracted idea? Is it reducible to biological characteristics? Is it a set of behaviors determined by...
Mistaken About Poverty
Perhaps it is because America is the land of liberty and opportunity that debates about poverty are especially intense in the United States. Americans and would-be Americans have long been told that if they work hard enough and persevere they can achieve their dreams. For many people, the mere existence of poverty—absolute or relative—raises doubts about that promise and the American experiment more generally. Is it true that America suffers more poverty than any other advanced democracy in the...
Jesus and Class Warfare
Plenty of Marxists have turned to the New Testament and the origins of Christianity. Memorable examples include the works of F.D. Maurice and Zhu Weizhi’s Jesus the Proletarian. After criticizing how so many translations of the New Testament soften Jesus’ teachings regarding material possessions, greed, and wealth, Orthodox theologian David Bentley Hart has gone so far to ask, “Are Christians supposed to be Communists?” In the Huffington Post, Dan Arel has even claimed that “Jesus was clearly a Marxist,...
Lord Jonathan Sacks: The West’s Rabbi
In October 1798, the president of the United States wrote to officers of the Massachusetts militia, acknowledging a limitation of federal rule. “We have no government,” John Adams wrote, “armed with power capable of contending with human passions unbridled by morality and religion. Avarice, ambition, and revenge or gallantry, would break the strongest cords of our Constitution as a whale goes through a net.” The nation that Adams had helped to found would require the parts of the body...
Creating an Economy of Inclusion
The poor have been the main subject of concern in the whole tradition of Catholic Social Teaching. The Catholic Church talks often about a “preferential option for the poor.” In recent years, many of the Church’s social teaching documents have been particularly focused on the needs of the poorest people in the world’s poorest countries. The first major analysis of this topic could be said to have been in the papal encyclical Populorum Progressio, published in 1967 by Pope...
How Dispensationalism Got Left Behind
Whether we like it or not, Americans, in one way or another, have all been indelibly shaped by dispensationalism. Such is the subtext of Daniel Hummel’s provocative telling of the rise and fall of dispensationalism in America. In a little less than 350 pages, Hummel traces how a relatively insignificant Irishman from the Plymouth Brethren, John Nelson Darby, prompted the proliferation of dispensational theology, especially its eschatology, or theology of the end times, among our ecclesiastical, cultural, and political...
Related Classification
Copyright 2023-2024 - www.mreligion.com All Rights Reserved