Home
/
RELIGION & LIBERTY ONLINE
/
How government regulation—not free markets—caused the financial crisis
How government regulation—not free markets—caused the financial crisis
Apr 26, 2025 12:52 AM

Note: Last week I asked why conservative Christian outlets areincreasingly promoting socialist ideas and policies. My friend Jake Meador weighed in to help provide some perspective on this trend. Jake himself is the editor of an online Christian magazine—Mere Orthodoxy—that would be described as traditionalist conservative. While he is not a socialist, he admits he is somewhat sympathetic to the “emerging leftism” of young Christians, especially those within Catholic and evangelical circles.

There’s a lot to say in response to his article, “Young Christians and the Specter of Socialism.” My initial post in response, “How Christian conservatives are breeding Bolsheviks,” took a rather broad approach in explaining why it was not entirely the fault of young socialist sympathizers. In this post I want to address a single, narrow but substantive, point where I think Jake and many others are in error.

In his article Jake wrote: “We think, rightly or wrongly, that we lived through a fairly free market era. . . . We saw—and lived!—what a lack of regulation of banks did to the market.”

If Only Government Would Intervene in the Market . . .

Here we are a decade after the start of the Subprime Mortgage Crisis of 2007 and many people still believe the primary cause was excessive freedom and a corresponding lack of government intervention in housing and financial markets. But is that belief warranted? Let’s look at a handful of the ways the government did (and does) intervene in the housing market:

The government intervenes, through the Federal Reserve, to stabilize prices—including the price of housing—by managing the supply of money.

The government intervenes, also through the Federal Reserve, to influence interest rates, which affects the interest rates on mortgages.

The government intervenes, through the tax code, by setting the home mortgage interest deduction, which induces homebuyers to buy more expensive houses than they otherwise would, thereby increasing indebtedness.

The government intervenes, through housing policy, to influence the types, number, and location of new homes, thereby reducing the supply of housing.

The government intervenes, through financial regulations, to protect fixed-amount creditors (e.g., banks) against loss should their financial institution fail because they’ve made bad loans to homebuyers.

The government intervenes, through the Federal Housing Administration (FHA), to guarantee mortgages of e borrowers.

The government intervenes, through the Government National Mortgage Association (Ginnie Mae), to sell securitized mortgage loans made by FHA in the credit market.

The government intervenes, through the government-sponsored enterprise known as the Federal National Mortgage Association (Fannie Mae), to increase the number of lenders in the mortgage market.

The government intervenes, through the government-sponsored enterprise known as the Federal Home Loan Mortgage Corporation (Freddie Mac), to buy mortgages on the secondary market, pools them, and sells them as amortgage-backed securityto investors.

The government intervenes, through housing regulation, to require lenders to give mortgage loans to people regardless of their ability to pay.

Is it really possible that the cause was a lack of government intervention?

Jake himself doesn’t directly deny the government intervenes in the housing market. His claim is that the “lack of regulation of banks” increased free markets in way that caused the crisis.

This is exactly backwards. As I’ll show, it was regulation of banks (and other financial institutions) that caused the subprime mortgage crisis that sparked the broader financial crisis.

Subprime Problems Caused by a Subprime Government

In the thirty years prior to the financial crises, there was no significant deregulation of financial institutions. If the problem was lack of regulation, why did the problem not occur sooner? Because in reality it wasn’t deregulation that caused the crises to occur but rather the addition of regulations.

In an attempt to increase home ownership, especially among the lower economic classes, the government imposed in 1992 a requirement on Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac to increase the number of subprime mortgages. Eventually, other private lenders covered by government regulation (especially the Community Reinvestment Act) were also required to issue more subprime loans.

mon misperception is that “subprime” refers to the interest rate on the loans. What subprime actually refers to is the credit score of the individual taking out the mortgage—the credit score is below (“sub”) what would normally be required to secure a loan. A credit score is one type of signal that is used by sellers of mortgages to determine whether the buyer is willing and/or able to fulfill their payment obligation. What the government was therefore requiring through regulation was that the market not only ignore this risk signal but be forced by law to give mortgage loans to people who had a documented history of being unable to pay lesser debts.

While this regulation increased the number of risky subprime loans that could be issued, consumers with poor credit scores were still somewhat discouraged from buying homes because of the relatively high interest rates being charged for mortgages (from 1992 to 2011, the average national mortgage rate bounced between 6.5 and 9 percent). However, after the terrorist attacks in September 2011, the Federal Reserve attempted to prop up the economy by lowering interest rates—a government intervention that affected the interest rates on mortgages.

Now that subprime borrowers could get a better rate, the government-influenced demand for such loans exploded. As this chart by Eric Petroff shows, “subprime mortgageoriginations grew from $173 billion in 2001 to a record level of $665 billion in 2005—an increase of nearly 300 percent.

Government regulations also required Fannie and Freddie to meet quotas when they bought loans from banks and other mortgage originators. In 1992, 30 percent of the loans had to be made to people at or below the median e in munities. By 2007, the quota had almost doubled to 55 percent.

In a 2011 interview with The Atlantic, Peter Wallison, an appointee to the government’s Financial Crisis Inquiry Commission, explained how this single government regulation set the financial crisis in motion:

It is certainly possible to find prime mortgages among borrowers below the median e, but when half or more of the mortgages the GSEs [i.e., Fannie Mac, Freddie Mac] bought had to be made to people below that e level, it was inevitable that underwriting standards had to decline. And they did. By 2000, Fannie was offering no-downpayment loans. By 2002, Fannie and Freddie had bought well over $1 trillion of subprime and other low quality loans. Fannie and Freddie were by far the largest part of this effort, but the FHA, Federal Home Loan Banks, Veterans Administration and other agencies—all under congressional and HUD pressure—followed suit. This continued through the 1990s and 2000s until the housing bubble—created by all this government-backed spending—collapsed in 2007. As a result, in 2008, before the mortgage meltdown that triggered the crisis, there were 27 million subprime and other low quality mortgages in the US financial system. That was half of all mortgages. Of these, over 70% (19.2 million) were on the books of government agencies like Fannie and Freddie, so there is no doubt that the government created the demand for these weak loans; less than 30% (7.8 million) were held or distributed by the banks, which profited from the opportunity created by the government. When these mortgages failed in unprecedented numbers in 2008, driving down housing prices throughout the U.S., they weakened all financial institutions and caused the financial crisis.

To understand the significance of the government’s role in the subprime mortgage crisis, pare how the housing market would function in a free market.

Free Markets vs. Government Influenced Markets

In a free market in which people buy and sell voluntarily, without pulsion, neither the quantities traded nor the price at which trade takes place are subject to control by third parties. In a perfectly free market this would mean the government didn’t artificially determine such factors as interest rates or the supply of housing. But let’s use a modified free market in which the government simply doesn’t intervene in the process of mortgage underwriting, the process a lender uses to determine if the risk of offering a mortgage loan to a particular borrower under certain parameters is acceptable.

Without the government to bail out either the lender or the borrower, both parties would rely on time proven signals for creditworthiness. The mortgage underwriter would look at the borrower’s credit history to see how they previously handled credit. They would look at the e level and ensure that the mortgage e ratio was not too high (e.g., above 30 percent). They might even ask for a down payment to reduce the ratio of the loan to the value of the home and to ensure the borrower had “skin in the game.”

Each of these factors would limit the number of mortgages that were approved, thereby reducing the demand for home ownership. This reduced demand would also prevent home prices from ing artificially inflated, limiting the number of homeowners who suffered from a delusion that they were wealthy simply because the price of their homes had increased.

Now let’s look at how government regulation subverted the normal market process.

The government made it clear that they were willing to bail out both the borrower and the lender, creating moral hazard on both sides. Certain mortgage underwriters were told not to look at the borrower’s credit history to see how they previously handled credit, but to give them a mortgage even if they had a history of failing to repay their debts. They were also not only told to downplay e levels but were required to give half of all mortgage they had underwritten to people who were below the median e in munity. They were also told to forgo downpayments, thereby increasing the ratio of loan to home value and ensuring borrowers would suffer no significant financial lose if they defaulted on their loans.

Each of these factors increased the number of mortgages that were approved, thereby increasing the demand for home ownership. This artificially increased demand led to the “housing bubble” where home prices were artificially inflated. It also lead to a widespread wealth delusion among homeowners who would take out loans backed by the equity of their artificially inflated home values.

As the Federal Reserve points out, the mortgage debt of U.S. households rose from 61 percent of GDP in 1998 to 97 percent in 2006. Now consider that half these mortgages—an equivalent of nearly half the GDP—were subprime loans and were bound to have a high default rate. Consider also that the government agreed to bail out not only the borrowers and the lenders but also the financial institutions that bought these securities because the American taxpayer was bearing the risk.

Too often defenders of government intervention focus on the non-government factors that contributed and exasperated the crisis. While those factors are significant, we shouldn’t overlook the fact that there would have been no financial crisis without the government regulation and intervention that lead to the subprime mortgage crisis.

Indeed, advocates of the free market were right all along when we warned that it was all but inevitable that these government interventions would lead to a crisis.

This is but one reason why Christians sympathetic to socialism should reconsider their support for government intervention in economic affairs. In the next post we’ll consider why they should be more willing to support free markets.

Related:In October the Acton Institute will be sponsoring a conference titled,Toward a Free and Virtuous Society: Marxism a Century after the Bolshevik Revolution.

Comments
Welcome to mreligion comments! Please keep conversations courteous and on-topic. To fosterproductive and respectful conversations, you may see comments from our Community Managers.
Sign up to post
Sort by
Show More Comments
RELIGION & LIBERTY ONLINE
How to Love Liberty More Than a Libertarian Economist
I have a deep and abiding love for liberty—which is why I find myself so often in disagreement with libertarians. Libertarians love liberty too, of course, but they tend to love liberty a bit differently. I love liberty in an earthy, elemental way. I love liberty because I need it—like I need air and food—for human flourishing. In contrast, the libertarians I’ve encountered tend to love liberty primarily as an abstraction. Indeed, the most ideologically consistent libertarians I know seem...
Constitutional Cases and the Four Cardinal Virtues
Should virtue be a consideration in judicial decisionmaking? Indiana Law Professor R. George Wright makes an intriguing argument for why the four cardinal virtues could be useful in interpreting constitutional cases: Judges typically decide constitutional cases by referring to one or more legal precedents, rules, tests, principles, doctrines, or policies. This Article mends supplementing this standard approach with fully legitimate and appropriate attention to what many cultures have long recognized as the four basic cardinal virtues of practical wisdom or...
How to Steal a Bike in New York City
Edmund Burke didn’t really say it, but it still rings true: All that is necessary for the triumph of evil is that good men do nothing. In a test of this maxim, filmmaker Casey Neistat tries to steal his own bike in several locations around New York City and finds that most people do nothing about it—even when it’s done right in front of a police station. I recently spent a couple of days conducting a bike theft experiment, which...
Lord Acton and the Power of the Historian
Looking through my back stacks of periodicals the other day I ran across a review in Books & Culture by David Bebbington, “Macaulay in the Dock,” of a recent biography of Thomas Babington Macaulay. The essay takes its point of departure in Lord Acton’s characterization of Macaulay as “one of the greatest of all writers and masters, although I think him utterly base, contemptible and odious.” As Bebbington writes, “Acton, a towering intellectual of the later 19th century, was at...
Let’s Change Hearts and Minds (and Laws, Too)
Few clichés are so widespread within the evangelical subculture, says Matthew Lee Anderson, as the notion that our witness must be one of “changing hearts and minds.” In careful hands, the idea is at best ambiguous. At worst it reinforces the sort of interior-oriented individualism that allows for and perpetuates a blissful naivete about how institutions and structures shape our dispositions and thoughts. In less than careful hands, the phrase drives a wedge between law and culture by attempting to...
Is Work a Curse?
Is work a curse, a result of mankind’s fall from grace? Not according to the Book of Genesis. As Hugh Whelchel, Executive Director of the Institute for Faith, Work & Economics, explains, what Adam was called to do in the garden is what we are still called to do in our work today: Humanity was created by God to cultivate and keep God’s creation, which included developing it and protecting it. You see, we were created to be stewards of...
Integral Human Development
The Journal of Markets & Morality is planning a theme issue for the Spring of 2013: “Integral Human Development,” i.e. the synthesis of human freedom and responsibility necessary for the material and spiritual enrichment of human life. According to Pope Benedict XVI, Integral human development presupposes the responsible freedom of the individual and of peoples: no structure can guarantee this development over and above human responsibility. (Caritas in Veritate 17) There is a delicate balance between the material and the...
Italy’s Tax Man Takes Aim at the Vatican
Kishore Jayabalan, the Acton Institute’s Rome office director, was interviewed by the Zenit news agency in an article titled, “Is Taxing the Church a Real Solution for Italy?” In the article, Jayabalan discusses the history of the Italian state and its imposition of property taxes on the Roman Catholic Church’s land holdings, residences and non-profit businesses. Sometimes in the past, particularly under Napoleonic rule and before the Lateran Pacts, the institution of property tax was often a subject of state...
Obamacare’s Religious Rubes
The White House has a plan to mobilize prayer vigils in front of the Supreme Court in defense of Obamacare. It was reported that the administration met with leaders at non-profit organizations and religious officials who support the new health care law. The court takes up the constitutional test of the health care mandate in a couple of weeks. The mandate has now been challenged in 26 states. Cue the same stale big government religious prophets who confuse statism and...
Reagan, Whittaker Chambers, and the Threat to Freedom
Over at the Liberty Law Blog, there is an excellent post titled “Ronald Reagan, Whittaker Chambers, and the Dialogue of Liberty” by Alan Snyder. Snyder delves into the influence Chambers had on Reagan and how their worldviews differed as well. Many conservatives and scholars felt Chambers’ prediction that the West was on the losing side of history in the battle against Marxism collapsed after the fall of the Iron Curtain and the Soviet Union. For many, the ideas of Chambers...
Related Classification
Copyright 2023-2025 - www.mreligion.com All Rights Reserved