Home
/
RELIGION & LIBERTY ONLINE
/
How government regulation—not free markets—caused the financial crisis
How government regulation—not free markets—caused the financial crisis
May 9, 2025 4:59 AM

Note: Last week I asked why conservative Christian outlets areincreasingly promoting socialist ideas and policies. My friend Jake Meador weighed in to help provide some perspective on this trend. Jake himself is the editor of an online Christian magazine—Mere Orthodoxy—that would be described as traditionalist conservative. While he is not a socialist, he admits he is somewhat sympathetic to the “emerging leftism” of young Christians, especially those within Catholic and evangelical circles.

There’s a lot to say in response to his article, “Young Christians and the Specter of Socialism.” My initial post in response, “How Christian conservatives are breeding Bolsheviks,” took a rather broad approach in explaining why it was not entirely the fault of young socialist sympathizers. In this post I want to address a single, narrow but substantive, point where I think Jake and many others are in error.

In his article Jake wrote: “We think, rightly or wrongly, that we lived through a fairly free market era. . . . We saw—and lived!—what a lack of regulation of banks did to the market.”

If Only Government Would Intervene in the Market . . .

Here we are a decade after the start of the Subprime Mortgage Crisis of 2007 and many people still believe the primary cause was excessive freedom and a corresponding lack of government intervention in housing and financial markets. But is that belief warranted? Let’s look at a handful of the ways the government did (and does) intervene in the housing market:

The government intervenes, through the Federal Reserve, to stabilize prices—including the price of housing—by managing the supply of money.

The government intervenes, also through the Federal Reserve, to influence interest rates, which affects the interest rates on mortgages.

The government intervenes, through the tax code, by setting the home mortgage interest deduction, which induces homebuyers to buy more expensive houses than they otherwise would, thereby increasing indebtedness.

The government intervenes, through housing policy, to influence the types, number, and location of new homes, thereby reducing the supply of housing.

The government intervenes, through financial regulations, to protect fixed-amount creditors (e.g., banks) against loss should their financial institution fail because they’ve made bad loans to homebuyers.

The government intervenes, through the Federal Housing Administration (FHA), to guarantee mortgages of e borrowers.

The government intervenes, through the Government National Mortgage Association (Ginnie Mae), to sell securitized mortgage loans made by FHA in the credit market.

The government intervenes, through the government-sponsored enterprise known as the Federal National Mortgage Association (Fannie Mae), to increase the number of lenders in the mortgage market.

The government intervenes, through the government-sponsored enterprise known as the Federal Home Loan Mortgage Corporation (Freddie Mac), to buy mortgages on the secondary market, pools them, and sells them as amortgage-backed securityto investors.

The government intervenes, through housing regulation, to require lenders to give mortgage loans to people regardless of their ability to pay.

Is it really possible that the cause was a lack of government intervention?

Jake himself doesn’t directly deny the government intervenes in the housing market. His claim is that the “lack of regulation of banks” increased free markets in way that caused the crisis.

This is exactly backwards. As I’ll show, it was regulation of banks (and other financial institutions) that caused the subprime mortgage crisis that sparked the broader financial crisis.

Subprime Problems Caused by a Subprime Government

In the thirty years prior to the financial crises, there was no significant deregulation of financial institutions. If the problem was lack of regulation, why did the problem not occur sooner? Because in reality it wasn’t deregulation that caused the crises to occur but rather the addition of regulations.

In an attempt to increase home ownership, especially among the lower economic classes, the government imposed in 1992 a requirement on Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac to increase the number of subprime mortgages. Eventually, other private lenders covered by government regulation (especially the Community Reinvestment Act) were also required to issue more subprime loans.

mon misperception is that “subprime” refers to the interest rate on the loans. What subprime actually refers to is the credit score of the individual taking out the mortgage—the credit score is below (“sub”) what would normally be required to secure a loan. A credit score is one type of signal that is used by sellers of mortgages to determine whether the buyer is willing and/or able to fulfill their payment obligation. What the government was therefore requiring through regulation was that the market not only ignore this risk signal but be forced by law to give mortgage loans to people who had a documented history of being unable to pay lesser debts.

While this regulation increased the number of risky subprime loans that could be issued, consumers with poor credit scores were still somewhat discouraged from buying homes because of the relatively high interest rates being charged for mortgages (from 1992 to 2011, the average national mortgage rate bounced between 6.5 and 9 percent). However, after the terrorist attacks in September 2011, the Federal Reserve attempted to prop up the economy by lowering interest rates—a government intervention that affected the interest rates on mortgages.

Now that subprime borrowers could get a better rate, the government-influenced demand for such loans exploded. As this chart by Eric Petroff shows, “subprime mortgageoriginations grew from $173 billion in 2001 to a record level of $665 billion in 2005—an increase of nearly 300 percent.

Government regulations also required Fannie and Freddie to meet quotas when they bought loans from banks and other mortgage originators. In 1992, 30 percent of the loans had to be made to people at or below the median e in munities. By 2007, the quota had almost doubled to 55 percent.

In a 2011 interview with The Atlantic, Peter Wallison, an appointee to the government’s Financial Crisis Inquiry Commission, explained how this single government regulation set the financial crisis in motion:

It is certainly possible to find prime mortgages among borrowers below the median e, but when half or more of the mortgages the GSEs [i.e., Fannie Mac, Freddie Mac] bought had to be made to people below that e level, it was inevitable that underwriting standards had to decline. And they did. By 2000, Fannie was offering no-downpayment loans. By 2002, Fannie and Freddie had bought well over $1 trillion of subprime and other low quality loans. Fannie and Freddie were by far the largest part of this effort, but the FHA, Federal Home Loan Banks, Veterans Administration and other agencies—all under congressional and HUD pressure—followed suit. This continued through the 1990s and 2000s until the housing bubble—created by all this government-backed spending—collapsed in 2007. As a result, in 2008, before the mortgage meltdown that triggered the crisis, there were 27 million subprime and other low quality mortgages in the US financial system. That was half of all mortgages. Of these, over 70% (19.2 million) were on the books of government agencies like Fannie and Freddie, so there is no doubt that the government created the demand for these weak loans; less than 30% (7.8 million) were held or distributed by the banks, which profited from the opportunity created by the government. When these mortgages failed in unprecedented numbers in 2008, driving down housing prices throughout the U.S., they weakened all financial institutions and caused the financial crisis.

To understand the significance of the government’s role in the subprime mortgage crisis, pare how the housing market would function in a free market.

Free Markets vs. Government Influenced Markets

In a free market in which people buy and sell voluntarily, without pulsion, neither the quantities traded nor the price at which trade takes place are subject to control by third parties. In a perfectly free market this would mean the government didn’t artificially determine such factors as interest rates or the supply of housing. But let’s use a modified free market in which the government simply doesn’t intervene in the process of mortgage underwriting, the process a lender uses to determine if the risk of offering a mortgage loan to a particular borrower under certain parameters is acceptable.

Without the government to bail out either the lender or the borrower, both parties would rely on time proven signals for creditworthiness. The mortgage underwriter would look at the borrower’s credit history to see how they previously handled credit. They would look at the e level and ensure that the mortgage e ratio was not too high (e.g., above 30 percent). They might even ask for a down payment to reduce the ratio of the loan to the value of the home and to ensure the borrower had “skin in the game.”

Each of these factors would limit the number of mortgages that were approved, thereby reducing the demand for home ownership. This reduced demand would also prevent home prices from ing artificially inflated, limiting the number of homeowners who suffered from a delusion that they were wealthy simply because the price of their homes had increased.

Now let’s look at how government regulation subverted the normal market process.

The government made it clear that they were willing to bail out both the borrower and the lender, creating moral hazard on both sides. Certain mortgage underwriters were told not to look at the borrower’s credit history to see how they previously handled credit, but to give them a mortgage even if they had a history of failing to repay their debts. They were also not only told to downplay e levels but were required to give half of all mortgage they had underwritten to people who were below the median e in munity. They were also told to forgo downpayments, thereby increasing the ratio of loan to home value and ensuring borrowers would suffer no significant financial lose if they defaulted on their loans.

Each of these factors increased the number of mortgages that were approved, thereby increasing the demand for home ownership. This artificially increased demand led to the “housing bubble” where home prices were artificially inflated. It also lead to a widespread wealth delusion among homeowners who would take out loans backed by the equity of their artificially inflated home values.

As the Federal Reserve points out, the mortgage debt of U.S. households rose from 61 percent of GDP in 1998 to 97 percent in 2006. Now consider that half these mortgages—an equivalent of nearly half the GDP—were subprime loans and were bound to have a high default rate. Consider also that the government agreed to bail out not only the borrowers and the lenders but also the financial institutions that bought these securities because the American taxpayer was bearing the risk.

Too often defenders of government intervention focus on the non-government factors that contributed and exasperated the crisis. While those factors are significant, we shouldn’t overlook the fact that there would have been no financial crisis without the government regulation and intervention that lead to the subprime mortgage crisis.

Indeed, advocates of the free market were right all along when we warned that it was all but inevitable that these government interventions would lead to a crisis.

This is but one reason why Christians sympathetic to socialism should reconsider their support for government intervention in economic affairs. In the next post we’ll consider why they should be more willing to support free markets.

Related:In October the Acton Institute will be sponsoring a conference titled,Toward a Free and Virtuous Society: Marxism a Century after the Bolshevik Revolution.

Comments
Welcome to mreligion comments! Please keep conversations courteous and on-topic. To fosterproductive and respectful conversations, you may see comments from our Community Managers.
Sign up to post
Sort by
Show More Comments
RELIGION & LIBERTY ONLINE
Creating a Culture That Lasts: Matthew Lee Anderson on ‘Radical Christianity’
I recently expressed my reservations about David Platt’s approach to “radical Christianity,” noting that, outside of embracing certain Biblical constraints (e.g. tithing), we should be wary of cramming God’s will into our own cookie-cutter molds for how wealth should be carved up and divvied out. In this month’s cover story inChristianity Today, my good friend Matthew Lee Anderson of Mere Orthodoxy does a nice job of summarizing some additional issues surrounding the broader array of “radical Christianity” books and movements....
Orthodoxy and Natural Law: A Reappraisal
At Ethika Politika today, I examine the recent critique by David Bentley Hart in the most recent issue ofFirst Things of the use of natural law in public discourse in my article, “Natural Law, Public Policy, and the Uncanny Voice of Conscience.” Ultimately, I offer a measured critique—somewhat agreeing with, but mostly critical of Hart’s position—pointing out Hart’s oversight of the vital role of conscience in classic natural law theory. What I find so bizarre, and have for some time...
Sirico: The Drama and Reality of Choosing a New Pope
In today’s The Detroit News, the Rev. Robert Sirico seeks to set aside some of the rumors, skewered Hollywood depictions, and media predictions that swirl around any papal conclave. Of course, this time is decidedly different, as the cardinals ing together not after the death of a pope, but one’s retirement. There is much talk throughout all the Church as to whom the next pope will be, and as Fr. Sirico points out, “[n]o one, not even the most well-informed...
Rand Paul Knows What We Know: Power Corrupts
After nearly 13 hours of speaking in an attempt to stall the confirmation of CIA Director nominee John Brennan, Sen. Rand Paul ended his filibuster. The filibuster is a grandiose method of legislative stalling, requiring the speaker to hold the floor, talking the entire time and not sitting down. In essence, one tries to talk a bill to death. The most famous fictitious depiction of the filibuster is probably is Frank Capra’s Mr. Smith Goes To Washington. Paul Rand, as...
As You Sow’s Grim Reaping
Religious groups seeking to serve myriad liberal agendas during the 2013 shareholder proxy resolution season look no further than As You Sow, a group dedicated to “large-scale systemic change by establishing sustainable and equitable corporate practices.” AYS will unveil its Proxy Preview on March 7. Trumpeted as the “Bible for socially progressive foundations, religious groups, pension funds, and tax-exempt organizations” by the Chicago Tribune, this year’s preview predictably includes such “issues” as hydraulic fracturing; e-waste recycling; waste disposal; and pushing...
Beyond the State and Market
At Fieldnotes Magazine, Matthew Kaemingk has an excellent article on why Christians should care about intermediary institutions: When presented with almost any social problem (education, health care, poverty, family life, and so on), today’s leaders typically point to one of two possible solutions—a freer market or a stronger state. But in opposition to these rather myopic solutions, I think there is a plex and biblical lens through which leaders can consider the social eco-system and the people who move around...
The Gospel and the Church: Turning Criminals into Co-Creators
I’m just back from the republic of Texas and Acton’s Toward a Free and Virtuous Society conference. One of my fellow lecturers was Southwestern Baptist Theological Seminary professor Ben Phillips. In between sessions, he showed me a recent Houston television news piece on SWBTS’s Darrington prison extension, where Phillips and other Southwestern profs are bringing prisoners to Christ, with a plan to send graduates of the program to other Texas prisons. Many of these men may grow old and die...
Why Culture Matters for Social Mobility
Over the next decade one of the key arguments between progressives and conservatives will be over the significance of e and wealth inequality. Many conservatives cannot fathom how the idea that some people have more money than others is inherently problematic, which is why the discussions seem so alien to us. While it may seem uncharitable, I agree with Anthony Bradley that much, if not most, of the progressive fascination with e and wealth inequality is due to the “deep...
Architecture, Human Flourishing, and Health Care
In a recent issue of Metropolis Magazine, Thomas de Monchaux tells the story of an amazing lesson about innovation that Americans can learn from Rwandans. This is no surprise, but readers will learn that burdensome government regulations stifle innovation and undermine human flourishing. De Monchaux recounts the story of Michael Murphy, executive director and co-founder of the Boston-based MASS Design Group, and Alan Ricks, MASS cofounder and COO, attempting to take what they learned from building health care facilitates and...
Audio: Discussing ‘Becoming Europe’ on African-American Conservatives
Samuel Gregg recently spoke with Marie Stroughter from African-American Conservatives. They discuss Gregg’s new book, ing Europe: Economic Decline, Culture, and How America Can Avoid a European Future. Stroughter asked Gregg about the dichotomy between “cuddle capitalism” (the European social model) and a dynamic market economy. Gregg says that Americans are more and more choosing a ‘Europeanized’ economy favoring security over economic liberty. Listen to the full audio here: [Audio: You can purchase the hardcover or eBook version of ing...
Related Classification
Copyright 2023-2025 - www.mreligion.com All Rights Reserved