Home
/
RELIGION & LIBERTY ONLINE
/
Every Market Form in a Single Chart
Every Market Form in a Single Chart
Jul 18, 2025 8:00 PM

Reading through the German economist Walter Eucken’s work The Foundation of Economics (1951), I came across one of the most helpful charts for economic analysis I have yet to find. In it, Eucken gives every possible form of market in a single table:

The Foundation of Economics, p. 158

Eucken adds four qualifications that are important to keep in mind:

“These forms of market are actual forms which have been or are to be found in actual economic life (often blended with one another, and existing alongside the forms of a centrally directed economy). They are not given a priori. They are discovered with their distinguishing characteristics by studying the planning data of those taking part in the market….”“Under each particular form of market a man can act according to different principles, for example, that of maximum net receipts or that of optimum output….”“Each of these forms of market can appear in four types: both open, both closed, or closed on either side only.”“Fixing of prices by the state occupies a special position, since it can follow any form of market and has different effects accordingly…. For example, the significance of coal prices being fixed by the state varies according to whether petitive, oligopolistic, or monopolistic supply, or some other form of market, exists, or whether both sides of the market are open, or whether the supply side is closed by an investment veto. Governmental price-fixing is to be treated as a variant of the different market forms and not as a special market form of its own.”

So, what does this amount to?

In the first place, Eucken emphasizes that these forms are determined through observation of actual market arrangements and interactions. Furthermore, in any given economy these forms will coexist along side one another.

Thus, in the United States, we have instances of semi-oligopolistic arrangements of supply petitive demand in the case of college textbooks, for example. Most textbooks are published by a few big publishers, who tend to exploit their position of privilege by publishing new editions every year to drive up sales prices and drive down resale prices. This is semi-oligopolistic because a professor may choose books of other or smaller publishers, or books of other formats, such as digital. Yet the place of prominence of a few textbook publishers and their sales practices affects the practices of everyone else involved.

At the same time, in the same country, we have a supply semi-monopoly in the case of the US Postal Service, who alone has the right to use citizens’ mailboxes. Competitors with no such exclusive privilege do exist (FedEx, UPS, and so on). Thus the USPS has a supply monopoly on mail delivery to one’s mailbox, but not on mail delivery in general.

In the second place, a wide variety of motivations may govern market actors — no form requires that a person be greedy or benevolent, for example. Though, I would add, the question of who is to benefit from a move from one to another does raise the question of motivation. Motivation may be various and undetermined, but that does not make it irrelevant.

Third, while the chart gives 25 different market arrangements, the number of actual forms is really 100. Both supply and demand can be either open or closed. “The ‘closed’ forms of supply and demand differ from the ‘open’ in a single but very important respect,” writes Eucken,

that is, the “closure” of supply and demand may be due to government prohibition or to the customs and opinions of the people.The closure can arise out of the general economic policy of the state or of a class or city, or it may be due to existing suppliers and demanders having a special interest to obstruct ers, or both these may work together.

By open and closed, here, Eucken refers to the possibility of petitors to enter the market, either on the supply or the demand side. If supply or demand is open, it means that new market actors can enter the market as suppliers or buyers, respectively. On the other hand, if either is closed, then new actors have a barrier to entry — this is the goal of cronyism, to close supply as much as possible to concentrate economic power in only panies.

Furthermore, it is worth noting that Eucken recognized borderline cases: “If the German craftsman in 1938 had to go through a particular process of training, pass a difficult examination, and fulfil [sic] certain personal requirements to be admitted to a firm, was this a case of ‘open’ supply? Usually the answer will be no.” We might add, then, the prefix semi- to open and closed, thus quadrupling our possible market forms again to a total of 400.

Last, in the midst of any of these arrangements, any given market may be affected by government price fixing.

For Christians seeking to make prudent economic policy prescriptions, keeping Eucken’s chart handy can prove invaluable. Furthermore, as Eucken notes elsewhere, the lowest price with the least es the closer one moves toward petition, or equilibrium. No doubt he would also add the benefit when both supply and demand are open. It is open supply that Joseph Schumpeter argued mitigated the effects of monopoly through the process of creative destruction. As such, petition best serves both suppliers and demanders. With the lowest prices at the least cost to businesses, petition best serves the poor in that goods are more affordable, choices more plentiful, and jobs more available in conditions of petition.

Thus, those concerned with social justice can use Eucken’s table like a map to guide them. It helps us locate any given market interaction within the form of market (or interdependent markets, as is always the case) involved in any economic exchange. Knowing where we are, we can better assess where any particular policy might take us. A move from semi-monopoly to oligopoly, or from closed to semi-closed, may not seem like a good move if one only looks at the consequence and does not consider the starting point. However, when both are kept in mind, one can see how such moves are in the direction of greater economic freedom.

The last lesson that I would offer from Eucken’s table is that mon labels of capitalism and socialism need more precise definition to be useful. As Eucken notes, actually existing economies tend to be mixed in reality and display a bination of market forms. Yet, China is munist and the United States is still capitalist. The main difference seems to be a preference for private (capitalism) vs. public (socialism) ownership. But we can find state monopolies in the US and open markets of private actors in China.

plication raises another question for me. Since nearly all, if not all, modern economies are mixed, where then is there room for advocating a “third way”? Either everyone already is practicing a third way economic system, or the difference is a general preference between binary options, such as private vs. public ownership as outlined above, leaving no discernible room for a third way. Those Christians who advocate various third way, “Christian” economics (as if economics is necessarily anti-Christian if not labeled as such) need to spend some time wrestling with the various actual market forms in existence, not simply abstractly (a priori) but as they currently function in the real world and within the real limits plicate their reform.

Comments
Welcome to mreligion comments! Please keep conversations courteous and on-topic. To fosterproductive and respectful conversations, you may see comments from our Community Managers.
Sign up to post
Sort by
Show More Comments
RELIGION & LIBERTY ONLINE
Dodd-Frank: The Other Serious Threat
At least es at us head on. The greater legislative threat may be the one that most Americans have never heard of. Economist Scott Powell and Acton friend Jay Richards explain in a new piece in Barron’s: While Obamacare received more attention, the Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act, also known as Dodd-Frank after its Senate and House sponsors, … unleashed a new regulatory body, the Consumer Financial Protection Bureau, to operate with unprecedented power. Dodd-Frank became law in...
Is it really ‘aid’ if it goes to relatively wealthy nations?
Alan Duncan, an aid minister in the UK, says his government is “forced” to hand over large amounts of money to the EU’s foreign aid budget, but has no say in how the money is spent. The problem is that much of the $2 billion+ “aid” money (one-sixth of the British budget) goes to projects such as making a Moroccan water park more eco-friendly, an art project in St. Petersburg, and building a hotel and plex in Barbados. Britain’s International...
Did 2,362 Millionaires Get Unemployment Checks in 2009? (Answer: Yes they did.)
The Congressional Research Service (CRS), a group that works exclusively for the U.S. Congress, issued a report with one of the greatest titles I’ve ever seen on a government document: Receipt of Unemployment Insurance by e Unemployed Workers (“Millionaires”) Now the first nine words are nothing special, typical policy-wonk speak. But whoever added in the word “millionaires” with scare quotes and parentheses is a genius. Most people would have been nodding off around the word “Insurance” but seeing millionaires (that’s...
Markets and culture: A time to play, a time to pray
Faced with the prospect of a professional athletic career, a nearly-half million dollar salary, and a perfect lady, what’s not to like? Apparently, for Grant Desme, it was the noise and unrest of the world. Can a culture of life and the noise and tumult of the marketplace co-exist? Rev. Robert Sirico, reflecting on this, says they can, so long as it is not a place where: [C]apitalism…places the human person at the mercy of blind economic forces…What we propose,...
Rev. Sirico on Life, Work, and Human Flourishing
J.Q. Tomanek of Ignitum Today interviewed Rev. Sirico about life, work, human flourishing, and his new book, Defending the Free Market: JQ Tomanek: Back in the day, holiness was misinterpreted as a cleric or religious life thing. How can a lay Catholic practice their faith? What are some ways to sanctify our work as lay Catholics? Is “ora et labora” just a monk thing? Reverend Sirico: Yes, religious people are often tempted to e so “heavenly minded they are no...
Stop Apologizing for Our Liberties
You cannot apologize to a fanatic, says Lee Harris. It only serves to convince him that he was right all along: The last few weeks have witnessed a peculiar and disturbing spectacle: An American administration that has spent a great deal of time and energy apologizing for our liberties—in particular, for what many would regard as the foundation of all our other liberties, namely, the freedom to express our minds as we see fit. This signature freedom, of which Americans...
How were people On Call in Culture 165 years ago?
What is so special about 1837? That was the year Abraham Kuyper was born. September 29th is his 165th birthday. So we thought we would go back to 1837 and see how people were being On Call in Culture back then. We don’t know if they were all believers on a mission to bless the world, but by seeing what was going on 165 years ago, we hope you are encouraged to engage your world in 2012! How did people...
On Call with Dr. Pamela Casson
Dr. Pamela Casson, a pediatrician in Colorado Springs, knows what it means literally to be “On Call.” This week she shares with us in this video interview with Jon Hirst how she sees God working through her in her work with families, children and the world around her. Thank you Pamela for giving us an inside look at how you see your work as blessing the world. ...
Counting the Profit of a Third Party Choice
Joe Carter recently highlighted the discussion at Ethika Politika, the journal of the Center for Morality in Public Life, about the value of (not) voting, particularly the suggestion by Andrew Haines that in some cases there is a moral duty not to vote. This morning I respond with an analysis of the consequences of not voting, ultimately arguing that one must not neglect to count the cost of abstaining to vote for any particular office. One issue, however, that I...
Want to Help the Poor? Promote a Free Market in Health Care
Want to help the poor? Promote a free market in health care. That’s the argument made by John C. Goodman, author of the new book Priceless: Curing the Healthcare Crisis. Timothy Dalrymple recently talked with Goodman about the best approach for restoring free-market pricing mechanisms into the market for medical care and health insurance: Aren’t there some people, however, who have little of money and lots of time, and would prefer to wait in order to receive cheaper care? There...
Related Classification
Copyright 2023-2025 - www.mreligion.com All Rights Reserved