Home
/
RELIGION & LIBERTY ONLINE
/
Criminal justice reform: What does economics have to say?
Criminal justice reform: What does economics have to say?
Sep 21, 2024 3:41 AM

This is part two of a series on criminal justice reform. Read part one here.

For many, crime and criminal justice are not obvious economic issues, despite their effects on public budgets due to the cost of courts, policing, investigating crimes, and much more. Private efforts impose significant costs, as well, whether from house alarms, flood lights, or door locks, not to mention the costs incurred by victims.

But costs such as these are not the primary source of economic interest in crime and criminal justice. If economics is a study of human behavior, the economic way of thinking can inform our understanding of the causes and effects of criminal activity and help us predict the consequences of public policy aimed at criminal justice. Therefore, economic literacy is key to contemplating the recent criminal justice reform debate and the First Step Act, which the House passed and President Trump signed into law just last week.

While the applicability of economics to crime is now readily accepted by today’s economists, this has only been the case for about 50 years. In a 1968 article, Nobel Laureate Gary Becker made a critical contribution to our understanding of crime, arguing that criminal activity could be modeled like so many other behaviors, based on the consideration of costs and benefits. Becker’s work was groundbreaking in that it provided a way for thinking about criminal activity and the people mit crime within a generalizable model.

What provokes a person mit a crime? The prevailing notion before Becker’s work was that crimes mitted by those of a criminal type. Becker proposed something different—that the higher the cost of crime or the lower the benefit of crime, the less likely an individual would be mit a crime (and vice versa). That is, even those mit crimes are likely to respond in predictable ways to changes in costs and benefits.

For example, a person who has meaningful employment faces a higher cost of incarceration in the form of foregone wages and fulfillment than does a similar individual without such employment. We would predict, then, that the former is less likely mit a crime, other things held constant. Similarly, an individual who would have to separate from family if incarcerated would incur a greater psychological cost of crime, and be less likely than an individual with fewer interpersonal connections mit a crime. As another example, the longer the probable sentence associated with a crime, the higher the cost to the potential offender and the less likely that person is mit a crime.

The length of criminal sentences has attracted a lot of attention as part of the debate about criminal justice reform. Some advocates assert that there are victimless crimes that are overcriminalized by the harshness of the sentences they receive. While many advocacy groups work for reducing or eliminating so-called mandatory minimum sentences, most are not entirely opposed to sentencing guidelines. Guidelines provide a predictability that some advocates consider consistent with justice, because a potential offender would know the likely consequences and understand that they should be applied impartially. The economically literate might also think that a potential offender’s understanding of the consequences of his criminal activity is important in the calculation of the net benefit of crime through the thought process modeled by Becker.

A Beckerian framework is not just helpful in predicting who mit a crime or who will e a “criminal.” It is also helpful predicting recidivism risk for the already incarcerated, who will one day reenter society. Imagine a former offender who returns to society and finds a set of munity, and employment attachments that are meaningful and rewarding. His likelihood of recidivism should be less than a similar person who finds himself with “nothing to lose” when faced with the prospect of another criminal act. This suggests that prison and sentencing reforms should be made with an eye toward re-entry. The provision in the First Step Act that would require placing a convicted offender in a prison within 500 miles of his primary residence would likely help to maintain family munity ties for incarcerated people. If an institution with appropriate security is available closer to an offender’s home, this is an appropriate investment in the offender’s wellbeing, his family’s wellbeing, and his later reentry prospects. In the final post of this series, I will detail more of the provisions of the First Step Act and the effects that economics would predict.

Building on Becker’s seminal work, a large literature within economics has identified causal connections between policy and criminal activity. With Dr. David Phillips of the University of Notre Dame, I coauthored an article on sentencing guidelines using a large dataset on mon crimes in Michigan. Our goal was to determine whether longer sentences always reduce future criminal activity. With data on retail fraud (including high-value shoplifting) and repeated drunk driving (third offense or more), we found that a more severe sentence did reduce recidivism for retail fraud offenders but not for those convicted of drunk driving. This result is consistent with a concern suggested in the first post in this series—that, where substance abuse or addictive behavior is involved, incarceration may not reduce recidivism as well as rehabilitation.

In general, economists have an important contribution to make to the discussion of criminal justice reform. First, economists are aware of mon social scientific adage that “correlation does not imply causation.” In the context of my coauthored research, it meant that we were not easily convinced that longer sentences were the cause of crimes later in life, even though people who received longer sentences did, on mit more crimes later in life. We suspect that judges see more serious crimes or more troubled offenders as indicating a higher risk of criminal activity in the future and respond rationally to that risk by lengthening the sentence. Economists are aware of this kind of challenge but also equipped to handle it with tools of statistical analysis less often employed by other disciplines or practitioners.

Second, economists and the economically literate more broadly are aware that good intentions are not synonymous with achieving the desired results. Human behavior is plex and rooted in self-interest, making it difficult to predict the full set of consequences for a policy, for example. The tough-on-crime era that preceded today’s popular “smart justice” movement was well-intended. It’s harsh sentencing regime also might have increased criminal activity through recidivism by reducing former offenders’ connections at home and in the labor market, creating the revolving door effect.

Another example of an unintended consequence is found in many states that have made it illegal for employers to inquire about an applicant’s criminal history in the early stages of job application. The intention of these “ban the box” laws is to increase opportunity for former offenders by allowing them to get further along in an application process before disclosing their relevant history and, in some cases, reduce racial disparities in employment. As a ing article by economists Jennifer Doleac and Benjamin Hansen finds, the result is far from what was intended. Specifically, African American and Hispanic men are less likely to be moved through the application process. The basic explanation is that, when employers wish to avoid interviewing former offenders but they cannot identify who has a criminal history, they will select for further consideration fewer applications from populations with higher average criminal history.

These lessons of economic literacy should inform the response to the First Step Act in its call for “evidence-based” programming in prisons. First, the prevalence of unintended consequences backs up the demand for a solid basis in evidence. Second, to tackle the causality challenge, evidence must be high-quality, based on large datasets, and discovered through the best statistical techniques available. It should also be rooted in solid economic theory that recognizes that incentives matter to people—whether former offender or not.

Image: Barbed Wire Chain Link

Comments
Welcome to mreligion comments! Please keep conversations courteous and on-topic. To fosterproductive and respectful conversations, you may see comments from our Community Managers.
Sign up to post
Sort by
Show More Comments
RELIGION & LIBERTY ONLINE
P.J. O’Rourke Addresses the Supreme Court, References Full House, Gilmore Girls, and The Avengers
An amicus brief is a learned treatise submitted by anamicus curiae(Latin for “friend of the court”), someone who is not a party to a case who offers information that bears on the case but that has not been solicited by any of the parties to assist a court. The amicus brief is a way to introduce concerns ensuring that the possibly broad legal effects of a court decision will not depend solely on the parties directly involved in the case....
Video: 60 Minutes Looks at ISIS Destruction of Christianity in Iraq
“60 Minutes” correspondent Lara Logan interviewed Iraqi Christians for a report that aired March 22. There will be mercial embedded at the start off the video, but just get past it. Logan’s interview, and the images of the destruction wrought by ISIS, vividly illustrate what this persecution means for more than 125,000 of Iraq’s Christians who have abandoned homes, villages and churches in the face of this barbaric assault. She interviewed Nicodemus Sharaf, archbishop of the Syriac Orthodox Church in...
Corruption And Bribery: The Cost Of Health Care In Central And Eastern Europe
It is no secret that rule of law in places like Slovakia is weak. Corruption, pay-offs, bribes and twisted use of power often pass for “rule of law.” However, this problem has infected health care as well, which means those who are able to bribe the doctor or health care worker is the one who will get the care. The Economist describes Communist-era corruption as a holdover infesting much of central and eastern Europe, and not just in health care....
Radio Free Acton: Gene Veith on Reformation and Vocation
A few weeks back, Acton ed Gene Edward Veith to the Mark Murray Auditorium as part of the 2015 Acton Lecture Series. This week, I had the opportunity to talk with Veith for this edition of Radio Free Acton. We discuss the influence of the Protestant Reformation on the development of capitalism, Luther’s beliefs on vocation, and how young people can discern their vocations as they contemplate their futures. You can listen to the podcast via the audio player below;...
‘Men, Some Say, Are Just Passé’
Christina Hoff Sommers, of American Enterprise Institute, takes on the idea of men being obsolete. Civilization now needs empathy, social intelligence, emotional knowledge – right? And that’s where females excel. So do we still need men? ...
Analysis: Russia’s Orthodox Soft Power
For us the rebirth of Russia is inextricably tied, first of all, with spiritual rebirth … and if Russia is the largest Orthodox power [pravoslavnaya dershava], then Greece and Athos are its source. —Vladimir Putin during a state visit to Mount Athos, September 2005. Writing for the Carnegie Council, Nicolai N. Petro says that Russian President Vladimir Putin’s “call for greater respect for traditional cultural and religious identities was either missed or ignored in the West. One reason, I suspect,...
Video: Rev. Robert A. Sirico Interviewed on Argentinian Television – Poverty, Politics, and Pope Francis
Acton Institute President and Co-Founder Rev. Robert A. Sirico was in Argentina last week for Acton’s conference in Buenos Aires on Christianity and the Foundations of a Free Society, which is part of a series of Acton conferences being held around the world on the relationship between religious and economic freedom. While he was there, he was interviewed on Infobae.tvand spoke about the problems of poverty that Argentina is struggling with, and also addressed the relationship between Pope Francis and...
The Fortunate Son’s Secret to Success
It ain’t me, it ain’t me, I ain’t no senator’s son, son It ain’t me, it ain’t me, I ain’t no fortunate one, no “Fortunate Son” – Creedence Clearwater Revival What do Al Gore, George W. Bush, Mitt Romney, Barry Bonds, Peyton and Eli Manning, Aage Bohrs, and Michael Douglas all have mon? Each of them reached the same level of success as their fathers in a petitive field. We like to think that the U.S. is a meritocracy, a...
The Loneliness of the Fortunate
“Rembrandt The Hundred Guilder Print” by Rembrandt – www.rijksmuseum.nl: Home: Info. Licensed under Public Domain via Wikimedia Commons. “No, those who labor and are heavy-laden do not all look the way Rembrandt drew them in his ‘Hundred Guilder’ picture—poverty-stricken, miserable, sick, leprous, ragged, with worn, furrowed faces. They are also found concealed behind happy-looking, youthful faces and brilliantly successful lives. There are people who feel utterly forsaken in the midst of high society, to whom everything in their lives seems...
In Aleppo, Syria’s Christians See Assad Regime as Last Hope for Survival
A columnist for Al-Monitor who writes under the pseudonym Edward Dark visited Siryan Adeemeh, or Old Siryan, an elevated area in the regime-controlled west of Aleppo, the largest city in Syria. Dark wanted to “gauge the sentiment” of this area, which he describes as a working-class neighborhood home to Christian Arabs of several denominations and also inhabited by a sizable Muslim and Kurdish population. “It’s one of the few areas of Aleppo where churches outnumber mosques, munal relations had always...
Related Classification
Copyright 2023-2024 - www.mreligion.com All Rights Reserved