Home
/
RELIGION & LIBERTY ONLINE
/
Claudia Goldin Is the Ideal Academic Researcher
Claudia Goldin Is the Ideal Academic Researcher
Mar 17, 2025 12:07 PM

The latest recipient of the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences has contributed much useful data in understanding the role of women in the workforce. Her restraint in policy prescriptions may, in fact, be her greatest contribution of all.

Read More…

Harvard’s Claudia Goldin is our newest Nobel laureate in economics. Her accumulated efforts have helped us better understand women’s roles in the labor market—both historically and in contemporary society.

It’s worth noting that the economics prize isn’t one of the awards funded by Alfred Nobel’s initial endowment. While the original prizes—physics, chemistry, physiology/medicine, literature, and peace—were first awarded in 1901, the economics award came much later. The “Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel” (its official name) is funded by the Bank of Sweden and wasn’t first awarded until 1969.

In recent years, it’s e mon for the economics award to be shared by two or three scholars working in related areas. In the past 15 years, for example, the prize was given to a single recipient just three times: to Jean Tirole in 2014, Angus Deaton in 2015, and Richard Thaler in 2017. This is just one of the ways in which this year’s award is notable: Goldin didn’t have to share it with anyone.

Goldin’s body of work is impressive. It has helped us understand the mix of cultural, social, and market-based forces that drive labor market es for women, including their participation, wages, and decisions regarding whether and when to have children. Perhaps most impressive of all, though, is mitment to high-quality research: while she’s careful in her descriptions and analysis of labor market dynamics as they relate to women, she rarely takes a position on how to change those dynamics if you don’t like them. And we like that about Goldin; she’s an academic researcher to her core.

What are the insights we’d be missing in the absence of her prize-winning research?

For starters, though we tend to think of female participation in the labor force as a relatively recent phenomenon—driven, at least in part, by artificial contraception, the equal-rights movement, and greater access to higher education—it was quite high for much of human history, mainly out of necessity. By examining sources such as time-use surveys, census data, and industrial statistics, Goldin pieced together evidence that the fraction of women participating in the labor force was much larger at the end of the 1890s than had previously been thought. Moreover, this phenomenon seems to stretch back as far as the late 1700s.

For at least a century, many women participated in the labor force. Yet this fact was missed when many census and other public documents listed “wife” as a married woman’s primary occupation. While they were certainly wives, many also labored at tasks beyond what economists might refer to as “domestic production.” For example, women worked alongside their husbands on farms or in family businesses. Children often did as well, out of necessity, though Goldin’s work deals mainly with adult female participation. It was mon for women to take on work outside family farms and businesses—perhaps working in cottage industries, where production could take place either in the family home or somewhere nearby. One of Goldin’s many striking findings: the employment rate for married women at the close of the 19th century was nearly three times greater than previous estimates indicated.

As industrialization progressed, with its ensuing urbanization and growth in factory jobs, Goldin finds that married women grew less likely to participate in the labor force. The mix of available jobs was shifting away from the sort of work that could be carried out within the family home or at least nearby, close to children and other family members.

Women returned to the labor force in the 20th century, however, and Goldin’s work points to several key factors driving this return. First, while industrialization reduced the likelihood that women—especially married ones—would enter the labor force, a large and growing service sector that hadn’t previously existed provided new job opportunities for women. Changing cultural norms and expectations, as well as the increased pursuit of higher education, also contributed to this trend. Goldin’s work highlights how expectations as to whether and how long they would work informed young women’s investment in higher education, leading to slow and persistent changes over time.

Goldin and others point to artificial contraception as another factor in women’s growing presence in the workforce. The ability of young families to choose how many children to have—and when—made it possible for many women to begin a career, step away from it when parenting called, and return to the workforce later. This observation also informs Goldin’s work regarding earnings gaps between men and women. An abundance of research now indicates that wage differences between men and women are small prior to the arrival of a family’s first child. Almost immediately, earnings for women fall relative to those of men. And this event can lead to persistent differences between women and men, especially in professions that require long hours or unpredictable schedules. Stated another way, it’s not surprising that the percentage mercial airline pilots who are female is significantly lower than the percentage found among local elementary school teachers. Advancement as an airline pilot is tough: even pleting flight school—which can cost $60,000+ dollars—flying for mercial airline requires at least 1,500 hours. And being a pilot, by definition, requires being away from home and family—whether or not a pilot is female. While female labor-force participation has risen steadily throughout the last century, it’s happened in jobs and careers that offer flexibility not found in other occupations.

One factor you likely didn’t see mentioned in news reporting about Goldin’s work is the role played by modern household appliances in increasing female labor-force participation rates. Yet it’s widely agreed among economists that modern inventions—like electric and gas stoves (instead of wood-burning ones!), vacuum cleaners, indoor automatic washing machines and dryers, microwave ovens, and even the Swiffer!—have made it possible for families to save time doing the household tasks that confront every family and to think creatively about what to do with all the time they’ve saved. For many, this has meant that families of all kinds have more freedom to make choices that are the best fit for them, including having more women earning money outside the home.

While we admire Goldin’s steadfast work in this area, we also appreciate the fact that she avoids the temptation to step into the role of policy advocate. Goldin is a serious economist who asks great questions, finds data where no one else can, and follows the trail wherever it leads. She’s not looking for any “right answers”: she’s merely trying to understand the world better.

Years ago, John Neville Keynes—father of John Maynard Keynes—identified three forms that economics can take. The first, positive economics, confines itself to questions of facts and empirical relationships. The second, normative economics, involves value judgments about how things should be. For example, positive economics can tell you what the unemployment rate is but it can never tell you whether it should be lower and why. While most of us have heard of these first two—positive and normative—Neville Keynes’ third form of economics is what he referred to as “art”: the part of economics that can advise you, based on positive economics, how to go about pursuing a particular normative goal.

Goldin’s work provides a variety of insights on what has allowed women to enter and remain in the labor force: the ability to work at or close to home, control over when and how many children to have, and flexible schedules. We are thankful that, throughout her brilliant career, Goldin has remained steadfastly in the realm of positive economics—leaving the “art,” the squabbling over the “right answer,” to politicians and interest groups.

Comments
Welcome to mreligion comments! Please keep conversations courteous and on-topic. To fosterproductive and respectful conversations, you may see comments from our Community Managers.
Sign up to post
Sort by
Show More Comments
RELIGION & LIBERTY ONLINE
Writing Tips for Your On Call in Culture Blog Entry
“Think, Think, Think” –Pooh It’s always hard to sit down and write. There are a million distractions that tempt us away from the keyboard or notepad and entangle us in the details of life. Not that these details are bad. In fact, as munity focused on being On Call in Culture, many of those details are the whole purpose. But before you get out there and answer the calling that God has put on your life as a dentist, professor,...
What Christian Education Is Not
“Each generation needs to re-own the rationale for Christian education,” says philosopher James K.A. Smith, “to ask ourselves ‘Why did we do this?’ and ‘Should we keep doing this?’” In answering such questions, Smith notes, “it might be helpful to point out what Christian education is not”: First, Christian education is not meant to be merely “safe” education. The impetus for Christian schooling is not a protectionist concern, driven by fear, to sequester children from the big, bad world. Christian...
Video: Chuck Colson speaks at the Abraham Kuyper & Leo XIII Conference
On October 31, 1998, Charles Colson came to Calvin College in Grand Rapids, Michigan to deliver the closing address at Acton’s “The Legacy of Abraham Kuyper & Leo XIII” conference, sponsored jointly with Calvin Seminary. “This is a momentous time for the Church as we reflect on two thousand years since the birth of Christ, and as we approach the millenium. And the question, I suspect, that all of us are asking and that the Church should be asking across...
Jacoby, D’Souza debate Religion in the Public Square
Susan Jacoby and Dinesh D’Souza met here in Grand Rapids at Fountain Street Church on Thursday, April 26, to debate the merits of religion in public discourse. The debate, co-sponsored by The Intercollegiate Studies Institute and the Hauenstein Center for Presidential Studies, was titled, “Is Christianity Good for American Politics?” Susan Jacoby is program director at The Center for Inquiry and author of The Age of American Unreason and Alger Hiss and The Battle for History. She argued for the...
The Heritage Guide to the Constitution
Our friends at the Heritage Foundation have created an invaluable online tool for learning about the U.S. Constitution: The Heritage Guide to the Constitution is intended to provide a brief and accurate explanation of each clause of the Constitution as envisioned by the Framers and as applied in contemporary law. Its particular aim is to provide lawmakers with a means to defend their role and to fulfill their responsibilities in our constitutional order. Yet while the Guide will provide a...
Are Young Millennials Less Religious or Simply Young?
Joe Carter recently posted a summary of a new studyconducted jointly by Public Religion Research Institute and Georgetown University’s Berkley Center for Religion, Peace, and World Affairs that shows that college-aged Millennials (18-24 year olds) “report significant levels of movement from the religious affiliation of their childhood, mostly toward identifying as religiously unaffiliated.” He also noted the tendency of college-aged Millennials to be more politically liberal. Just yesterday, the same study was highlighted by Robert Jones of the Washington Post,...
Why Religious Liberty Is Important for Institutions
Is religious liberty only for individuals or also for institutions? As Ryan Messmore explains, America’s founders thought that the Constitution’s “first freedom” is for both: True liberty must take account of the relational aspect of human nature. And truereligious liberty, in particular, must entail the freedom to exercise one’s faith in the various relationships and joint activities of day-to-day life. In other words, religious freedom applies to participation in institutions. Each one of those institutions—our particular school, church, workplace, etc.—takes...
The Next Civil Rights Movement
During last year’s Acton University—have you signed up for this year yet?—Nelson Kloosterman gave a lecture on the subject of school choice and private education. In the latest issue of Comment magazine, Kloosterman expands on his claim that parental choice is “the next civil rights movement“: Let me begin with some ments designed to set up the discussion that follows. First, and most importantly, I believe that the fundamental issue in this matter involves parental choice, even though the far...
Was Thomas More a proto-communist?
In Utopia, many modern intellectuals say Sir Thomas More advocates an ideal political and social order without private petition, citizens quarreling over worldly possessions, poverty and other “evils” supposedly brought on by a market-based society. At least that is the way social liberals, including left-leaning Christians, tend to interpret this great saint’s 1516 literary masterpiece, believing the English Catholic statesman’s work presents his vision of an ideal monwealth modeled on the early Church (even ifthose munist experiments failed). Recently, Istituto...
Fair Trade or Free Trade?
Is ‘fair trade’ more fair or more just than free trade? While free trade has been increasingly maligned, The Fair Trade movement has e increasingly popular over the last several years. Many see this movement as a way to help people in the developing world and as a more just alternative to free trade. On the other hand, others argue that fair trade creates an unfair advantage that tends to harm the poor. Dr. Victor Claar addresses this question in...
Related Classification
Copyright 2023-2025 - www.mreligion.com All Rights Reserved