Home
/
RELIGION & LIBERTY ONLINE
/
Thinking about the ethics and economics of ‘price gouging’
Thinking about the ethics and economics of ‘price gouging’
Apr 21, 2025 6:22 PM

A reporter posted a picture on Twitter yesterday that showed a Best Buy in Houston charging $42 for a case of Dasani water. The picture also showed a case of Smartwater for $29, with a sign noting there was a “limited supply.”

Not surprisingly, the outrage on social media prodded Best Buy to quickly respond by claiming it was a mistake.

“As pany we are focused on helping, not hurting affected people,” pany said in a statement. “We’re sorry, and it won’t happen again.”

Best Buy, Inc. is a pany and the largest specialty retailer in the U.S. consumer electronics retail industry. They likely have many people on their staff who are savvy enough about economics to explain why the increased price on water was helping, not hurting affected people. Nevertheless, pany felt obligated to apologize and promise never to engage emergency surge pricing (i.e., when a seller responds to the excess demand during an emergency situation by increasing the price in order to again equalize market demand with available market supply).

I sympathize with Best Buy. While the economics of “price gouging” is rather simple and straightforward, the ethics of emergency surge pricing is counterintuitive plicated. It’s often difficult for people who are both morally and economically minded to decide what to think about such situations.

I wish I could offer a perspective on the issue that was not only based on sound economics and Christian ethics but also pelling to my fellow beliefs. If such a view exists, though, I certainly don’t know what it is—much less how to develop it into a convincing argument.

Instead, I’ll offer five beliefs I have related to emergency surge pricing during natural disasters and how I attempt to satisfactorily resolve the inherent contradictions and conflicts between them. The five beliefs are:

The morality of price gouging is context-specific. That is to say, price gouging may be morally licit in some situations and immoral in others.Emergency surge pricing benefits munity in aggregate even though it can cause harm at the level of the individual.Anti-price gouging laws are more harmful than helpful because they create shortages on the most urgently needed goods and services during emergencies.Because emergency surge pricing offends people’s sense of justice and fairness, defending such policies can make society less likely to support other free market initiatives that increase human flourishing.Emergency surge pricing has the most detrimental impact on poor individuals and families who are already the most vulnerable during such crisis situations. We have a moral obligation to resolve this problem.The morality of price gouging is context-specific. That is to say, price gouging may be morally licit in some situations and immoral in others.

Increasing the price of goods or services during an emergency is not inherently immoral since the price increase can lead to a more fair and equitable distribution of scarce resources. To know whether it is moral, however, requires understanding the specific context of a particular exchange (e.g., you have water to sell and I want to buy it) and how we should prioritize other moral duties.

As a Christian, I must always be aware that the moral legitimacy of economic decisions plex and context-specific. While a free market is often the best way to facilitate virtuous exchanges, not all exchanges in a free market are virtuous.

Emergency surge pricing benefits munity in aggregate even though it can cause harm at the level of the individual.

On an emotional level, I’d prefer to oppose emergency surge pricing. “Price gouging” just feels unfair, and intuitively seems like a violation of my Christian duty to love my neighbor. I can also imagine how I would feel if I were caught in a situation where the price of goods and services during an emergency exceed my ability to pay. Even if I had the money I would likely be outraged at the “unfairness” of what would appear to be profiting from my misery.

Yet if I set aside my emotional reaction I can clearly see the rational justifications for emergency surge pricing and how it can lead to more just distribution of goods and services. Rather than restate the economic case for “price gouging” I’ll simply suggest watching the video below or reading this defense by Donald J. Boudreaux.

Anti-price gouging laws are more harmful than helpful because they create shortages on the most urgently needed goods and services during emergencies.

About 70 percent of U.S. states (including Texas) have some form of price-gouging laws. While they may useful in an indirect manner (more on this in a moment), they are likely to cause more harm than good because they create shortages of goods and services. As Michael Giberson explains in the journal Regulation,

Economists and policy analysts opposed to price gouging laws have relied on the simple logic of price controls: if you cap price increases during an emergency, you discourage conservation of needed goods at exactly the time they are in high demand. Simultaneously, price caps discourage extraordinary supply efforts that would help bring goods in high demand into the affected area. In a classic case of unintended consequences, the law harms the very people whom lawmakers intend to help. The logic of supply and demand, so clear to economists, has had little effect on price gouging policies.

Giberson also highlights a 2007 paper in the Journal of Competition Law and Economics that examined the effects of price gouging laws and concluded a national law would have increased total economic losses during Hurricanes Katrina and Rita by nearly $2 billion, mostly from interference with incentives to bring goods and services to areas where they are most needed. In addition, they found that a national price gouging law would have left more of the economic burden of the storms on the states most directly hit, Louisiana and Mississippi, while moderating the economic consequences for the rest of the nation.

Because emergency surge pricing offends people’s sense of justice and fairness, defending such policies can make society less likely to support other free market initiatives that increase human flourishing.

The strongest defense I can make in favor of price gouging laws is a pragmatic one based on a reality that we might never be able to change: the majority of Americans will never accept the economic rational for why emergency surge price munities. Even when presented with convincing arguments for why price-gouging laws have a detrimental effect—and may lead to greater harm and suffering—most Americans will allow emotion to overwhelm economic reasoning.

In other words, if you can’t beat ‘em, join ‘em.

But why should we join them? Because if people despise emergency surge pricing and associate it with the free market, they are more likely to believe that the free market leads to similar harms. To prevent the public from opposing other free market policies that promote the general welfare, we may need to avoid defending emergency surge pricing.

The problem with this concession is that relies on a consequentialist, Machiavellian justification. In essence we would be saying, “Yes, people are harmed by anti-price gouging laws. But that’s a sacrifice we have to make to prevent people from supporting other types of harmful anti-free market policies.”

That’s not an approach I fortable with, which is why I believe we need to find a promise for how to replace anti-gouging laws.

Emergency surge pricing has the most detrimental impact on poor individuals and families who are already the most vulnerable during such crisis situations. We have a moral obligation to resolve this problem.

In general, emergency surge pricing alleviates hoarding and provides incentives to increase supply of goods and services in areas struck by disaster. This benefits everyone by ensuring that supplies are where they are most needed. However, we are left with the problem of how to make these resources available to poor individuals and families, many of whom may barely be able to afford normal prices.

While I don’t have a solution that is fully fleshed out, I have a proposal for how we might consider alleviating the problem: surge-pricing vouchers.

Prior to a natural disaster, individuals and families could apply to receive government-provided vouchers that would cover the cost difference between the normal price and the emergency surge price for a specific basket of essential goods and services.

For example, let’s imagine that a case of water normally sells for $10 but because of surge pricing the cost has risen to $25. A e buyer would pay the normal cost of the product ($10) and give the vender a voucher for the remainder ($15). To recoup the difference, the vendor would send the voucher to the government for reimbursement. (In lieu of anti-gouging laws the vendor would be required to accept vouchers during declared emergencies.)

There are other ways the vouchers could be designed to benefit the e individual. The vouchers could, for instance, cover the entire cost of a product and the government could recoup the normal cost at a later time. They could also be transferrable, allowing the e individual to sell or trade their voucher for something they’d prefer to have (such as cash).

No doubt there are many legitimate objections to this proposal. Designing and implementing the plan would be difficult and it would suffer from the same problems caused by any other government intervention, including increasing unforeseen and unfortunate consequences.

But even with these flaws a voucher system (or something similar) might be a better option than the laws we have in place.

Comments
Welcome to mreligion comments! Please keep conversations courteous and on-topic. To fosterproductive and respectful conversations, you may see comments from our Community Managers.
Sign up to post
Sort by
Show More Comments
RELIGION & LIBERTY ONLINE
Sen. Ben Sasse’s two-minute civics class
Earlier this week, during the confirmation hearing for Judge Brett Kavanaugh, Nebraska Senator Ben Sasse gave what David French calls a “short master class in civics and the role of the judiciary in the American constitutional republic.” This was the fourth point in Sen. Sasse’s 15 minute talk on “how we got here and how can we fix it.” To watch the entire brief speech, click here. ...
‘The great re-homing’: Why entrepreneurs are bringing business home
In the wake of massive economic disruption, many munities have been left by the wayside—whether due to technology, trade, or globalization. While rural factories have shuttered and farms have consolidated, job prospects and educational opportunities have abounded in America’s largest urban centers. Those shifts have brought plenty of benefits through an increased density of smarts, skills, and capital, but they’ve also introduced new risks, from the centralization of power to the fracturing of family munity to the diminishment of national...
Acton Institute statement on Richard M. DeVos Sr. (1926-2018)
Richard (Rich) M. DeVos exemplified the value of hard work, free enterprise and expansive philanthropy in building munities. The Acton Institute mourns the passing of DeVos, 92, who for decades was known for leadership in business, his dedication to the promotion of liberty, and his courage in maintaining and defending the free and virtuous society. “Rich DeVos never shrank from the conviction that the roots of liberty and the morally-charged life are to be found in the eternal truths of...
Unemployment as economic-spiritual indicator — August 2018 report
Series Note: Jobs are one of the most important aspects of a morally functioning economy. They help us serve the needs of our neighbors and lead to human flourishing both for the individual and munities. Conversely, not having a job can adversely affect spiritual and psychological well-being of individuals and families. Because unemployment is a spiritual problem, Christians in America need to understand and be aware of the monthly data on employment. Each month highlight the latest numbers we need...
Sin is a social contagion that threatens freedom
Note:This article is part of the ‘Principles Project,’ a list of principles, axioms, and beliefs that undergirda Christian view of economics, liberty, and virtue. Clickhereto read the introduction and other posts in this series. The Principle:#7D — Sin is a social contagion.(NB: This is a subset of theActon Core Principleon the Reality of Sin.) The Definitions: Sin — Rejecting or ignoring God in the world he created, rebelling against him by living without reference to him, not being or doing...
Alejandro Chafuen on Real Nazis in Argentina
Acton’s Alejandro Chafuen weighed-in at Forbes on the new Hollywood movie about the arrest and eventual trial of Nazi Adolph Eichman, Operation Finale. The movie is more than a historical reenactment for Chafuen, who recounts in his essay that a notorious Nazi once inhabited the Argentine neighborhood where Chafuen lived for 30 years. The Nazi who lived close to my family, Joseph Mengele, has been credited for being extremely astute in evading capture and changing addresses just in time. But...
Walmart’s T-shirt homage to mass murder
It is extremely concerning and offensive to find Walmart and other retailers promoting what they call “cool shirts“ — bright red tees emblazoned with the Soviet hammer and sickle, says Mari-Ann Kelam in this week’s Acton Commentary. “Making light of the mitted under and in the name munism shows ignorance and callousness.” As an Estonian-American living in Europe, I am embarrassed and pained. It is impossible to explain such flippancy to people here, many of whom suffered munism. People are...
Explainer: Judge Kavanaugh and why you should care about ‘Chevron deference’
Judge Brett Kavanaugh made a second appearance before the Senate Judiciary Committee today for his Supreme Court confirmation hearing. During questioning,Kavanaugh was asked about a controversial, but little-known, legal doctrine called “Chevrondeference.” Here’s what you should know about Kavanaugh’s position andwhy you should care about Chevron deference. What is the Chevron the Senate is referring to? The pany? Yes, though indirectly. Chevron, the corporation, was the plaintiff in the landmark Supreme Court case Chevron U.S.A., Inc. v. Natural Resources Defense...
A few words from Richard DeVos
Today is a sad day here at the Acton Institute as we mourn the passing of a longtime friend and supporter, Richard M. DeVos. You can read Acton’s statement on his passing that was posted earlier, which sketches the basic outlines of his life for those who may not be familiar with him. But we also thought it appropriate to share the video posted below. It documents a portion of his address at Acton’s2010 Anniversary Dinner, where he became one...
Against job-shaming: ‘Cosby’ actor reminds us of the dignity of work
After a decades-long career in film, theater, and education, actor Geoffrey Owens decided to take a part-time job as a cashier at Trader Joe’s. When customers and news outlets began posting photos of the actor bagging groceries, the ments included a mix of mockery and what Owens describes as “job-shaming.”Fortunately, according to Owens, “the shame part didn’t last very long.” “It hurt…I was really devastated,” Owens explained on Good Morning America, “but the period of devastation was so short.” Owens...
Related Classification
Copyright 2023-2025 - www.mreligion.com All Rights Reserved