Home
/
RELIGION & LIBERTY
/
Tariffs are Taxes
Tariffs are Taxes
Apr 20, 2025 6:56 AM

  For some time, public debate in the United States has questioned whether import tariffs are effective economic policy instruments. Can tariffs address trade imbalances and encourage domestic manufacturing? Is protection the key to securing prosperity?

  Tariffs have historically played this role in the United States. As the first Secretary of the Treasury, Alexander Hamilton implemented high tariffs to protect American industry from British imports, arguing that infant industries needed shielding to develop and compete. Hamilton’s strategy, however, also included subsidies and infrastructure investments, not just tariffs. These policies helped lay the foundation for American industrialization.

  In the late nineteenth century, tariffs—most notably the Morrill Tariff of 1861—shielded domestic producers from European competition and provided revenue. The Republican majorities of the Gilded Age embraced three pillars of economic policy: sound money under the gold standard, a business-friendly, lightly regulated domestic market, and tariffs as both a revenue source and a protective measure. In the early twentieth century, tariffs remained central to trade policy. The Smoot-Hawley Tariff Act of 1930 sought to protect American farmers and manufacturers but is now widely blamed for worsening the Great Depression. Other nations retaliated, reducing global trade and deepening economic hardship.

  These historical examples share a key characteristic: they took place under a gold standard or fixed exchange rate system. Under such regimes, tariffs could sometimes help reduce trade imbalances, but only through internal adjustments—such as deflationary pressure or lower domestic demand—rather than currency depreciation.

  In a fixed exchange rate or gold standard system, monetary policy is constrained, so trade deficits are corrected through shifts in domestic prices and wages rather than currency depreciation. If tariffs reduce imports, they slow the outflow of gold or foreign reserves, stabilizing the money supply. Since exchange rates remain fixed, however, competitiveness must be restored through lower domestic prices and wages, often leading to weaker domestic demand.

  At the same time, tariffs create a protected market for domestic industries, making imported goods more expensive and encouraging local production. Without currency depreciation benefiting foreign competitors, domestic manufacturers gain a stable environment to expand. Additionally, tariff revenues often fund infrastructure and industrial subsidies, further stimulating economic development. This was the strategy behind American industrialization in the nineteenth century and similar policies in Germany and Japan.

  This is not to say that under fixed gold or exchange rate regimes, tariffs were perfect. Far from that, they often protected inefficient industries, raised consumer prices, and provoked retaliation. While they were tolerable under a system of fixed exchange rates, they were never a straightforward economic good.

  The US deficit is driven by entitlement spending, tax policy, and broader structural factors—none of which can be meaningfully addressed by taxing imports.

  Today, the world operates under floating exchange rates, where tariffs behave differently. When a country imposes tariffs, its currency typically appreciates as capital flows adjust and demand for foreign currency falls. This appreciation makes exports more expensive and imports cheaper, neutralizing the intended protective effects of the tariff.

  Trade imbalances adjust primarily through currency fluctuations rather than shifts in domestic output. This makes tariffs largely self-defeating as a tool for addressing trade deficits. Instead of boosting domestic manufacturing, they tend to lead to a stronger currency, which counteracts the tariffs’ intended effects and leaves industries no more competitive than before. The real drivers of trade imbalances—such as national savings rates, capital formation, labor productivity, and capital flows—remain unchanged.

  If Tariffs Don’t Work as Intended, What Are They For?

  If tariffs do not significantly reduce trade imbalances or boost domestic manufacturing, what purpose do they serve? The most immediate answer is tax revenue. Tariffs function as an indirect tax on imports. While businesses and consumers ultimately bear the cost, the government collects additional revenue without needing to pass politically unpopular income tax hikes.

  Conservative voters are generally alienated by politicians raising taxes, but tariffs provide a politically convenient way to increase revenue. Policymakers can frame these taxes as a way to punish foreign competitors, winning over this otherwise skeptical demographic.

  Like direct taxation, tariffs do not necessarily trigger broad inflation—they simply change the relative prices of taxed goods. The currency appreciation that follows tariff imposition can partially offset price increases on imports. From a fiscal standpoint, tariffs increase government revenue while shifting the economic burden mostly toward the tradable sector.

  Yet, there is still one key consequence: taxes increase. Tariffs may be presented as an economic nationalist policy, but their immediate fiscal effect is to extract more real resources for the government. While their advocates promote them as tools for protecting domestic production and jobs, these effects are largely illusory under floating exchange rates. At best, any impact is temporary—assuming no retaliatory trade war ensues.

  Can Tariffs Solve America’s Deficit Problem?

  If tariffs are just a not-so-hidden tax increase, could they be a viable tool for addressing America’s budget deficit? Certainly not. The revenue generated by tariffs is insignificant compared to the scale of fiscal deficits, and their economic distortions outweigh any financial benefits.

  The US deficit is driven by entitlement spending, tax policy, and broader structural factors—none of which can be meaningfully addressed by taxing imports. Moreover, tariffs provoke retaliation, harming exports and disrupting industries that rely on global supply chains. They also fail to address the root causes of trade imbalances, which stem from macroeconomic conditions rather than unfair trade practices.

  Consider the foreign purchase of US assets. Investors buying US Treasuries must first buy US dollars, increasing demand for the currency. This means that if everything else remains equal, federal, state, and local fiscal imbalances create artificial demand for dollars, pushing the exchange rate higher. If the United States curbed its deficits, the demand for dollars would fall, making American-made goods more competitive globally.

  A Better Alternative: Fiscal Responsibility

  Tariffs on imports do not restore American producers’ competitiveness in a floating exchange rate system. Only a return to fiscal discipline truly could. Recent and historical cases of fiscal consolidation demonstrate that reducing deficits in a democracy is possible when political will is mustered. Lower deficits would reduce the artificially high demand for US dollars, leading to a lower US dollar Index that naturally enhances American competitiveness.

  Tariffs may be politically popular, but under a floating exchange rate system, they are ineffective at correcting trade imbalances or promoting domestic industry. Instead, they function primarily as a tax increase that disproportionately affects consumers and businesses reliant on tradable goods.

  The bottom line is, if policymakers are serious about fixing America’s trade and fiscal challenges, they should abandon outdated protectionist measures and focus on meaningful economic reforms. A stronger, more competitive economy will come not from artificial barriers to trade but from sound fiscal policies that address the true structural issues behind trade imbalances.

Comments
Welcome to mreligion comments! Please keep conversations courteous and on-topic. To fosterproductive and respectful conversations, you may see comments from our Community Managers.
Sign up to post
Sort by
Show More Comments
RELIGION & LIBERTY
Adam Smith and the Poor
Adam Smith did not seem to think that riches were requisite to happiness: “the beggar, who suns himself by the side of the highway, possesses that security which kings are fighting for” (The Theory of Moral Sentiments). But he did not mend beggary. The beggar here is not any beggar, but Diogenes the Cynic, who asked of Alexander the Great only to step back so as not to cast a shadow upon Diogenes as he reclined alongside the highway....
How Dispensationalism Got Left Behind
Whether we like it or not, Americans, in one way or another, have all been indelibly shaped by dispensationalism. Such is the subtext of Daniel Hummel’s provocative telling of the rise and fall of dispensationalism in America. In a little less than 350 pages, Hummel traces how a relatively insignificant Irishman from the Plymouth Brethren, John Nelson Darby, prompted the proliferation of dispensational theology, especially its eschatology, or theology of the end times, among our ecclesiastical, cultural, and political...
C.S. Lewis and the Apocalypse of Gender
From very nearly the beginning, Christianity has wrestled with the question of the body. Heretics from gnostics to docetists devalued physical reality and the body, while orthodox Christianity insisted that the physical world offers us true signs pointing to God. This quarrel persists today, and one form it takes is the general confusion among Christians and non-Christians alike about gender. Is gender an abstracted idea? Is it reducible to biological characteristics? Is it a set of behaviors determined by...
Creating an Economy of Inclusion
The poor have been the main subject of concern in the whole tradition of Catholic Social Teaching. The Catholic Church talks often about a “preferential option for the poor.” In recent years, many of the Church’s social teaching documents have been particularly focused on the needs of the poorest people in the world’s poorest countries. The first major analysis of this topic could be said to have been in the papal encyclical Populorum Progressio, published in 1967 by Pope...
Lord Jonathan Sacks: The West’s Rabbi
In October 1798, the president of the United States wrote to officers of the Massachusetts militia, acknowledging a limitation of federal rule. “We have no government,” John Adams wrote, “armed with power capable of contending with human passions unbridled by morality and religion. Avarice, ambition, and revenge or gallantry, would break the strongest cords of our Constitution as a whale goes through a net.” The nation that Adams had helped to found would require the parts of the body...
Mistaken About Poverty
Perhaps it is because America is the land of liberty and opportunity that debates about poverty are especially intense in the United States. Americans and would-be Americans have long been told that if they work hard enough and persevere they can achieve their dreams. For many people, the mere existence of poverty—absolute or relative—raises doubts about that promise and the American experiment more generally. Is it true that America suffers more poverty than any other advanced democracy in the...
Jesus and Class Warfare
Plenty of Marxists have turned to the New Testament and the origins of Christianity. Memorable examples include the works of F.D. Maurice and Zhu Weizhi’s Jesus the Proletarian. After criticizing how so many translations of the New Testament soften Jesus’ teachings regarding material possessions, greed, and wealth, Orthodox theologian David Bentley Hart has gone so far to ask, “Are Christians supposed to be Communists?” In the Huffington Post, Dan Arel has even claimed that “Jesus was clearly a Marxist,...
Up from the Liberal Founding
During the 20th century, scholars of the American founding generally believed that it was liberal. Specifically, they saw the founding as rooted in the political thought of 17th-century English philosopher John Locke. In addition, they saw Locke as a primarily secular thinker, one who sought to isolate the role of religion from political considerations except when necessary to prop up the various assumptions he made for natural rights. These included a divine creator responsible for a rational world for...
Spurgeon and the Poverty-Fighting Church
Religion & Liberty: Volume 33, Number 4 Spurgeon and the Poverty-Fighting Church by Christopher Parr • October 30, 2023 Portrait of Charles Spurgeon by Alexander Melville (1885) Charles Spurgeon was a young, zealous 15-year-old boy when he came to faith in Christ. A letter to his mother at the time captures the enthusiasm of his newfound Christian faith: “Oh, how I wish that I could do something for Christ.” God granted that wish, as Spurgeon would e “the prince of...
Conversation Starters with … Anne Bradley
Anne Bradley is an Acton affiliate scholar, the vice president of academic affairs at The Fund for American Studies, and professor of economics at The Institute of World Politics. There’s much talk about mon good capitalism” these days, especially from the New Right. Is this long overdue, that a hyper-individualism be beaten back, or is it merely cover for increasing state control of the economy? Let me begin by saying that I hate “capitalism with adjectives” in general. This...
Related Classification
Copyright 2023-2025 - www.mreligion.com All Rights Reserved